Minnesota Governor Tim Walz, the Democratic vice presidential nominee, recently urged his supporters to not “shy away from our progressive values. One person’s socialism is another person’s neighborliness.” Socialism is sharing a cup of sugar with the family across the street, and who could object to that?
Walz’s identification of socialism with neighborliness is reminiscent of Bernie Sanders’s remark that, “to me, socialism doesn’t mean state ownership of everything, by any means, it means creating a nation, and a world, in which all human beings have a decent standard of living.” Here Sanders equates socialism not with any particular set of economic institutions, but rather with the uncontroversial idea that we should create a world in which everyone has a decent standard of living.
Even socialist philosophers and writers are guilty of this kind of rhetorical sleight of hand. G.A. Cohen once argued that voluntarily sharing food and equipment with one’s friends on a camping trip is an embodiment of socialist principles. And according to George Orwell, socialism is the notion that “everyone does his fair share of the work and gets his fair share of the provisions;” he says that the merits of socialism so defined are “blatantly obvious.”
I agree with Orwell—to a point. It is obvious that we should want an economic system that fairly distributes burdens and benefits. But it’s not obvious that socialism is this system. Merely identifying socialism with a fair economic system is no more of a convincing defense of socialism than merely identifying capitalism with a fair economic system is a convincing defense of capitalism. This is a bit like someone arguing that the paleo diet is the healthiest diet because they’ll simply label whatever foods turn out to be the healthiest as “paleo.” To fruitfully compare capitalism and socialism, then, we need an understanding of the specific economic institutions that characterize socialism and capitalism.
At the most general level, socialist economies are those that mandate the collectivization of productive property. That is, they allow you to privately own “personal property” like your shoes, but not “productive property” like a shoe factory. Collectivization can be institutionalized in different ways. For instance, old-school socialists would favor state ownership of the shoe factory. But that style of socialist economy is less popular today given the overwhelming evidence that it is not prosperous, kind, or fair (see Venezuela for a recent example).
Contemporary socialists have therefore taken to advocating for workplace democracy: roughly, workers collectively own firms and make decisions democratically. This arrangement allows for market competition—worker-owned firms may openly compete with one another—and so avoids some of the traditional Hayekian critiques of socialism.
Still, it’s not clear to me that this style of socialism is all that neighborly. Sure, some people might prefer to become worker-owners of a democratically-run firm, just as some people might prefer to work remotely rather than in an office. But others might prefer a capitalist firm—and those people are out of luck under socialism. As the philosopher Robert Nozick points out, capitalism allows socialist-minded people to pool their resources together to create democratic worker cooperatives if they so choose, but socialism does not allow capitalist-minded people to create capitalist firms.
And there are plenty of good reasons why people might prefer capitalist firms. For example, as Don Lavoie notes, workers “may not want to take on the risk, expense, and responsibility involved in managing a firm.” He continues, “After all, there are potentially several advantages to workers who choose to specialize in earning wage income in order to be insulated from the vicissitudes of market competition. There is often an advantage in allowing someone else to be the boss and thereby reducing one’s concerns to the fulfillment of a wage contract, letting the management fret about the firm’s profit and loss statements.”
To illustrate the point, suppose Lance wants to start his own landscaping business and needs to hire an employee. Moe just wants stable employment and a steady wage; he doesn’t want a piece of the business and the headaches that come along with it. So Lance hires Moe to mow some customers’ lawns.
As a result of the wage contract, both Lance and Moe get what they want. Yet, as Nozick would say, this is one of many “capitalist acts between consenting adults” that must be prohibited by a socialist regime if it is to remain socialist. A socialist regime would compel Lance to give Moe a share of the business if he’s hired even though both parties would be worse off as a result. But forcing people into workplace arrangements they’d rather avoid is not kind or friendly; to the contrary, it sounds downright unneighborly.
Christopher Freiman is a Professor of General Business in the John Chambers College of Business and Economics at West Virginia University.
READER COMMENTS
john hare
Sep 11 2024 at 7:25pm
One socialist type example I’ve seen is two restaurants where the servers pool the tips and split them evenly. One had poor average service with the best servers moving on to greener pastures leaving the less motivated/skilled. That one went broke. Another one that splits tips does well by constant management control with one of the owners on the floor all the time. They go through a lot of high school students (apparently that young) and have about twice the servers on the floor as a similar competing restaurant.
Monte
Sep 11 2024 at 11:02pm
Nonsense! Socialism (democratic or otherwise) by any other name is still a zero-sum game. Tip-sharing is a perfect example, wherein the best servers are must help support the worst servers. It works the same in any capacity – all in the name of equality. To which I say Hawk Tuah! Give me pay-for-performance, or give me unemployment!*
*Too harsh?
David Seltzer
Sep 12 2024 at 3:58pm
Monte: Trenchant as always! Some years ago I started a healthcare facility. We were not non-profit! We were operating for a year when an employee making $150,000 per, came into my office and said since he was a partner, he wanted a bigger piece of the pie. His words. I told him he was an employee. If he wanted equity, come up with $300,000. Put his name on loan documents and understand there is liability associated with ownership as well as significant business risk. He balked and I summarily cashiered him.
Monte
Sep 12 2024 at 11:49pm
I can’t help but think his proposition initially brought a wry smile to your face. The audacity of some people never ceases to amaze.
Knut P. Heen
Sep 12 2024 at 8:12am
Socialism has nothing to do with equality. The Soviet Union practiced pay-for-performance in addition to the Gulag. Socialism is about taking power away from sovereign consumers and transferring that power to a sovereign central planning bureau. The central planners live in nice houses while the rest of the people live in tiny apartments.
I have heard stories from communist countries in which they ate the meat before the rest of the meal just to avoid risking to share with a neighbor who came by. Sharing enormous surpluses is a capitalist act. Hiding tiny amounts of meat from your neighbor is a communist act.
Monte
Sep 12 2024 at 11:38am
Theoretically, socialism seeks to reduce inequality by advocating for collective ownership through wealth redistribution, the so-called “transitional phase” between capitalism and communism. Under communism, private ownership of the means of production is abolished in an attempt to create a classless society and ensure an equitable distribution of resources, the intent being to eliminate presumed inequalities.
So pardon me if I say both at least pretend to be about equality.
Colin Sane
Sep 12 2024 at 4:34pm
of course, Nozick wasn’t talking about Capitalism and Socialism, but about Anarchy and State. maybe this is what Walz meant: someone might call themselves anarchist, but ask them further and they’ll actually say they’re anarcho-capitalist. someone might call themselves socialist, but ask further and they just want a stonger safety net.
the average Joe doesn’t have a clue what these words “really mean”. the “deliberative” part of “deliberative democracy” is about finding one policy which satisfies the desires of many disparate groups. making friends with the enemy isn’t a shameful thing: it’s the most productive aspect of deliberative democracy.
disclaimer: not involved in US politics: all I have to go on here is your own quote of Mr. Walz.
Monte
Sep 13 2024 at 10:09pm
All you have to do is look at his policies and who he’s aligned with politically to know what he meant, whether you’re involved with U.S. politics or from another planet.
Monte
Sep 14 2024 at 10:53am
https://www.dailysignal.com/2024/09/12/tim-walz-appointed-member-of-political-party-loyal-to-chinese-communists-to-state-board/
Ahmed Fares
Sep 12 2024 at 7:13pm
The Allure of Marxism … And Why It’s a Mistake by Blair Fix
Comments are closed.