The Problem With Economic Planning

Economic planning, where the government uses policies such as taxation, subsidies, spending, or nationalization, in order to direct economic outcomes, is back in vogue.  Its proponents often liken economic planning to planning done by individuals in the economy.  The difference, they claim, is that national economic planning can help accomplish larger economic, national, or social goals that the individual wouldn’t.

However, human beings are not infallible.  Even the best laid plans of mice and men run often go awry.  All plans, whether individual or centrally-derived, can fail.  Of course, economic planners recognize this fact.  In the case of failure, they often argue, the economic planner can just discard the current plan and readjust, just like the individual.  On its face, this argument sounds reasonable enough.  But this is a case where the economic way of thinking shines: incentives matter.  

Identifying a plan’s failure can sometimes be straightforward (although, as Donald Boudreaux points out, it is not always obvious): if some goal is established and the goal is not reached, we can say the plan failed.  However, why the plan failed is often a hard question to answer: did the plan fail because it is inherently a bad plan?  Or did the plan fail because it was poorly executed?  

Individual planners and economic planners face different incentives to understanding why a plan fails.  The individual planner, who faces most (if not all) of the costs and all of the benefits of their actions, faces strong incentives to figure out why a plan failed and whether it should be abandoned or not.  If my get-rich-quick plan is to sell tobacco-flavored toothpaste and nobody buys it, I face the incentive to figure out why.  If I keep investing my resources into tobacco-flavored toothpaste, I will certainly be made worse off: those resources have alternative uses and the benefits of using those resources to make tobacco-flavored toothpaste exceed the costs.  In other words, I have devoted too many resources to developing this product.  Given my goal (getting rich quick) and the fact I face the full cost of using those resources, I have the incentive to dump the plan as a failure and use my resources in a different way.

Economic planners do not face the same incentives.  They face neither the full costs or the full benefits of their plans.  Consequently, they face perverse incentives to find out why the plan failed.  If some economic planner decided that the sale of tobacco-flavored toothpaste was a national priority, how might they react to the failure of the plan?  Perhaps, by some stroke of luck, they would realize that people do not want tobacco-flavored toothpaste and abandon the plan altogether.  More likely, however, the planner would likely conclude that too few resources were devoted to producing tobacco-flavored toothpaste rather than too many resources.  The planner may devote more resources toward advertising or other means to accomplish their plan.  This is especially true if their job, say as the Director of the Federal Agency to Promote Tobacco-Flavored Toothpaste, depends on the success of the plan.  In short, while the economic planner could realize their plan has failed and abandon it, the incentives are not aligned to make this outcome likely.  

Tobacco-flavored toothpaste is a silly example, but we see this behavior all the time.  One example in particular comes to mind: the COVID-19 price controls.  During COVID-19, the Federal and many state governments imposed price controls on essential goods.  The logic was that it would preserve required equipment for hospitals and prevent price gouging.  However, shortages of these goods predictably appeared and hospitals had a difficult time acquiring the products.  Rather than recognize the plan had failed to increase goods available, the governments doubled down, blamed firms, and began prosecuting “hoarders” and “price gougers,” exacerbating the problem.  The shortages persisted and the very policies that created the failure remained (in fact, the policy actually made the pandemic worse).  The planners failed to see why their plan failed.

Bad policies persist in both the private and the public sector.  Planners are unwilling or unable to admit their plans have failed and adjust.  Poor managers cause firms to fail, inability to adjust causes individuals to go bankrupt.  However, when individual plans fail, those resources are freed up to go to other uses.  When economic plans fail, the government planners often pull on more resources, increasing waste.  

In conclusion, while it is possible that economic planning could work as a series of experiments, where the “good” are kept and the “bad” are discarded, we have little reason to think such an outcome is likely.  The incentives to understand why a plan has failed are simply not there.

 


Jon Murphy is an assistant professor of economics at Nicholls State University.

READER COMMENTS

Craig
Nov 7 2024 at 12:13pm

Mike Johnson’s recent comments on ‘Chips’ shows how quickly Republicans lose their relugion. He’s not alone, Reagan had VERs, tariffs for Harley Davidson and semiconductors, indeex pretty sure Sematech was some kind of private/government thing.

Indeed, its a shame there aren’t more of you at high school level, Professor Murphy because most obviously get 0 economics or vert little in college and I genuinely think basic understandings of opportunity cost would undermine support for such schemes, whethers its chips, potato chips, stadiums, washing machine factories in red/blue states alike.

 

Richard Fulmer
Nov 7 2024 at 2:17pm

There is also the problem of concentrated benefits and dispersed costs. Regardless of how dysfunctional a government program, there is likely someone who benefits from it and who therefore has a big incentive to lobby to keep the program in place. On the other hand, if the program only costs each taxpayer a few dollars a year, no one has much incentive to go to Washington and lobby for its cancellation. So, the companies that produces tobacco flavored toothpaste will spend big bucks to keep the program alive.

That’s why we still have the Jones Act, tariffs on sugar, and subsidies for corn-based ethanol.

David Seltzer
Nov 7 2024 at 5:11pm

Jon wrote, “The incentives to understand why a plan has failed are simply not there.” As you point out, it individuals face different incentives. In the Navy, I trained to box in the interservice tournament. During a heavy sparring session, I was knocked down. Between rounds, my trainer quietly asked me why that happened. I told him I lowered my hands, making my head an clear target. What was the plan to avoid further calamity? Keep my hands up. Getting floored was a strong incentive to acknowledge my error and correct it. Jon, When one of your students failed a test because they didn’t prepare, I suspect the F they earned was enough of an incentive to study diligently for your rather demanding final exam.

 

Knut P. Heen
Nov 11 2024 at 11:41am

You had the incentive to hold your hands up before you got knocked down too. Why did your behavior change?

Mactoul
Nov 8 2024 at 12:09am

Considering that these economic planners tend to be economists themselves, and the economic planning only exists as product of existence of economists themselves, it is very arguable whether the existence of economics as a field and economists as a profession has been a net positive for humanity,

Jon Murphy
Nov 8 2024 at 6:13am

Your conclusion doesn’t logically follow. Any science will have good and bad applications of itself. Those applications do not negate each other. The same chemistry that gives us clean water creates deadly poisons used in horrific acts. The same physics that lets us fly also make war possible. The same linguistics that gives us The Bible gives us evil books.

Indeed, I would argue (following the greatest scientists humanity has to offer) that a purpose of science is to understand when it can go right and when it can go wrong.

Besides, as a factual matter, your line of reasoning is incorrect. Economic planning predates economics. The field arose, in part, as a refutation of economic planning (eg Adam Smith’s lengthy refutation of mercantilism and protectionism in The Wealth of Nations). Economic planning fell out of favor in the 1800s. It didn’t come back into vogue until the 1900s. Then the task fell once again to economists to explain how the plans fell short and were positive harms.

Warren Platts
Nov 8 2024 at 4:47pm

(eg Adam Smith’s lengthy refutation of mercantilism and protectionism in The Wealth of Nations)

Professor Murphy, at least you’re now making a distinction between mercantilism and protectionism! That’s good! However, I would argue that the famous Scottish Commissioner for Managing and Causing to be Levied and Collected His Majesty’s Customs, and Subsidies and other Duties in that part of Great Britain called Scotland, and also the Duties of Excise upon all Salt and Rock Salt Imported or to be Imported into that part of Great Britain called Scotland was what I would call a mild protectionist..

Jon Murphy
Nov 8 2024 at 6:13pm

 what I would call a mild protectionist..

Yes, we all know.  But Smith himself explicitly rejects protectionism and calls for free trade, so we can say that your characterization is…anatopistic.

MarkW
Nov 8 2024 at 6:22am

It’s not just that planners don’t have the right incentives to figure out why the plans fail, they often have powerful incentives to attribute failure to the wrong things when an accurate diagnosis would be politically disadvantageous.  See, for example, Biden and Harris blaming the inflation in food prices on price gouging by grocery stores.  This is a corollary to Nozick’s joke about ‘normative sociology’ being ‘the study of what the causes of social problems ought to be’.  We can generally expect planners to follow such a normative approach to understanding failures of government programs — the identified causes of failures should never be things that embarrass their political bosses.

Jon Murphy
Nov 8 2024 at 6:15pm

Yes, you are correct.  That’s along the lines of what I was thinking when I was discussing the agency leader with the budget dependent on solving the issue.

MarkW
Nov 10 2024 at 7:59am

I noticed a nice example of this dynamic in a TV series my wife and I recently started watching — it’s called ‘For All Mankind’ and is an alternate history of NASA during the 60s and 70s.  In one episode, NASA has a serious accident and commissions an outside report.  The report identifies a underlying cause that would be deeply embarrassing to the president and his political allies (awarding a contract to a subpar, but politically connected firm).  Of course the report is classified and hidden rather than being published.

Knut P. Heen
Nov 11 2024 at 11:24am

I largely agree, but I am not sure about the incentive story.

There is a large literature in corporate finance showing that corporations don’t respond before they have to either. Bankruptcy and hostile takeovers are important mechanisms to take assets away from managers with bad plans and give the assets to managers with better plans.

People tend to marry their plans, so I think the important point is how easy it is to change personnel. Elections every four year and no possibility of bankruptcy is not a good starting point when the wrong person/plan was elected. Dictatorship is even worse.

We have a similar saying about science in Planck’s principle: science marches forward funeral by funeral. The old guys never change their mind. The old guys die and are replaced with a new generation with different ideas.

 

Jon Murphy
Nov 11 2024 at 12:17pm

I guess I don’t see how the example of the corporation undermines the incentive story.  It’s the same incentives at play.

Comments are closed.

RECENT POST

It is not because preserving the rule of law is a French problem that it has no relevance for the United States. Quite the contrary. The current minister of the Interior, the top cop in France, recently declared (see Nicolas Bastuk and Samuel Dufay, “L’État de droit est-il sacré?” or “Is the Rule of Law Sacre...

Read More

Alex Tabarrok has an excellent post at Marginal Revolution this morning explaining why he had and has confidence in prediction markets. It's very hard to argue, while predicting, against people who are putting their own money on their own predictions. Like Alex, I tracked those markets closely, which is why I was te...

Read More

Economic planning, where the government uses policies such as taxation, subsidies, spending, or nationalization, in order to direct economic outcomes, is back in vogue.  Its proponents often liken economic planning to planning done by individuals in the economy.  The difference, they claim, is that national economic ...

Read More