The Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation has an interesting accountability mechanism. After they make a major funding decision, they solicit pro and con memos on “roads not taken” – other ways they could have spent their money. Since the Gates Foundation recently decided not to back charter cities to help reduce global poverty, they asked me to write a memo to explain why they made a mistake. Here’s the full text of my memo, reprinted with permission:
To: The
Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation
From: Prof.
Bryan Caplan
Re: The
Case for Charter Cities
Anyone
serious about reducing world poverty must come to grips with a single key fact:
Redistribution from rich to poor has not and cannot solve more than a tiny
fraction of the problem. Even if you
could perfectly equalize income in
Third World nations with zero effect
on production, the citizens of Third World countries would remain mired in
poverty. Take Bangladesh. With a GDP of $256B and a population of 164M,
equalization would at best give each citizen an income of $1561 per year –
about $4 a day. Countries do not overcome
poverty by sharing production more equally.
They overcome poverty by increasing production – what economists call “economic
growth.”
At first
glance, increasing production seems extremely slow and difficult, requiring
decades of investment in education, infrastructure, political reform, and who
knows what else. But there turns out to
be one foolproof way for people from the Third World to drastically increase
their production overnight: move to the First World. “The Place Premium,” an important paper by
the Center for Global Development’s Michael Clemens, Claudio Montenegro, and
Lant Pritchett[1],
offers the most precise estimates of the benefits of migration. They find that the effect of country of
residence on income dwarfs the combined effects of poor education, poor health,
poor work habits, and all the other defects commonly ascribed to Third World
labor. Holding workers’ traits fixed,
moving a Haitian from Haiti to the United States increases his wage about ten times – a gain of 900%.
The lesson: Third World workers
are less productive than First World workers largely because they live in the
dysfunctional countries.
The first-best
solution to global poverty, therefore, is for the First World to allow much
higher levels of immigration. Unfortunately,
despite its low absolute level (annual U.S. immigration is well under 1% of its
population), immigration is already extremely unpopular. For the foreseeable future, significantly
more open borders – not to mention truly open borders – seem politically
impossible. The challenge, then, is to
figure out a close substitute for free migration from the Third World to the
First. This is the challenge that Paul
Romer’s increasingly influential “charter cities” proposal tries to meet.
The point
of charter cities is to peacefully create pockets of high-quality First World
governance in the heart of the Third World.
How? By persuading Third World
governments to create new self-governing cities exempt from most existing
laws. These new cities could be governed
by foreign law, and administered by foreign governments – or even a for-profit
corporation. While the specifics are intentionally
flexible, there are three core building blocks of any charter city:
- An uninhabited piece of city-sized land, provided
voluntarily by a host government. - A charter that specifies the rules that will govern the
new city. - The freedom for would-be charter city residents,
investors, and employers to move in or out.[2]
The success
of Hong Kong is a key inspiration. At
the dawn of British rule, the land area that is now Hong Kong was sparsely
inhabited. But it had one blessing
denied to the rest of China: British rules – written and unwritten, sheltered
by a 99-year treaty with the Chinese government. While the rest of China suffered through
cycles of chaos and tyranny, Hong Kong enjoyed stable, pro-growth rules. Foreign investors rightly judged it a secure and
fruitful place to invest. Ambitious
Chinese rightly judged it an inviting place to live and work. And thanks to that 99-year treaty, even
erratic Communist dictator Mao Zedong reluctantly tolerated Hong Kong’s
independence. By the time Hong Kong reverted
to mainland rule, it was not only a First World country, but a model for the
rest of China to emulate.
In principle,
Third World countries could put nationalistic prejudice aside and “import” the
written and unwritten rules that have made the West rich. But this is extremely difficult. Intense populist opposition aside, it is hard
to graft one country’s institutions on to another’s – especially when
entrenched interests fight you every step of the way. This is true in the business world as
well. Competitors often try and fail to
adopt leading firms’ “best practices.”
Corporate culture is notoriously stubborn. In both business and politics, success often
requires a clean slate. It is easier to open
a new WalMart than to make the Kmart chain better. Advocates of charter cities argue that is
also easier to bring in “outside management” to make a new city that works than
to reform existing countries that don’t.
As the
example of Hong Kong suggests, charter cities have both direct and indirect
benefits.
Directly,
each charter city would allow millions of people to better their lives by
integration with the world economy.
While critics often belittle this achievement as mere “cream-skimming,”
the sad truth is that much if not most of the world’s cream now curdles in
backwards farms and dysfunctional slums.
If the native entrepreneurs who built Hong Kong had been trapped in
mainland China, most would have wasted their lives in dead-end jobs on Maoist
communes or joined the Communist elite.
Hong Kong gave them opportunities to use talents that otherwise would have
gone to waste.
Indirectly,
each charter city is a beacon of enlightenment.
Hong Kong shined brightly enough to convince even dogmatic Chinese
Communist elites that private property, foreign investment, and economic
integration with the world economy were the way to go. Charter cities would be laboratories of
development. Successful models could be “copied
and pasted” in a matter of years, not decades.
And ultimately they might even shame their own national governments into
embracing transparent pro-growth policies.
The charter
cities concept is ideal for support by the Gates Foundation. Any
philanthropy that seeks to overcome global poverty should give charter cities a
fair hearing, but the Gates Foundation is more than just another philanthropy. The Gates Foundation stands for innovation,
entrepreneurship, and evidence-based policy.
Several of its Guiding Principles create a natural affinity with the
charter cities concept – especially Principle #5 (“Our focus… prioritizes
some of the most neglected issues.”), #6 (“We identify a specific point of
intervention and apply our efforts against a theory of change”), #7 (“We take
risks, make big bets, and move with urgency. We are in it for the long haul.”),
and #11 (“Delivering results with the resources we have been given is of the
utmost importance–and we seek and share information about those results.”) Charter cities is one of the few
intellectually serious proposals on the table for drastically reducing world
poverty. A “big bet” of Gates funding
and credibility on this “neglected issue” could easily jump start a virtuous
circle of progress.
Another upside
of charter cities is that there is virtually no downside. A charter city begins on empty land. It can only grow by voluntary migration of
workers and investors. If no one chooses
to relocate, they’re no worse off than they would have been if the charter city
had never existed. If efforts to start
charter cities fail, at least they won’t harm the very people they’re intended
to help.
In
contrast, the paths the Gates Foundation currently intends to pursue sound
worse than doing nothing. “Build
capacity of organizations working on-the-ground with the urban poor” and
“Integrate the voice of the poor into the planning process” sound
compassionate. But they could easily
further retard the only poverty-reduction process that really works: economic
growth. My first book, The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why
Democracies Choose Bad Policies (Princeton University Press 2007) finds
that economic illiteracy is especially pronounced among the least
educated. They are especially likely to
misperceive the economy as a zero-sum game, to fear economic interaction with
foreigners, and to naively focus on employment rather than production. Frankly, voices like this need less influence
on policy, not more.
If you
really want to learn what benefits the world’s poor, don’t ask them to become
amateur social scientists. See how they
vote with their feet. Build charter
cities, and the world’s poor will come.
Bryan
Caplan
Professor
of Economics
Mercatus
Center
George
Mason University
Further Reading
Paul
Romer. September 28, 2009. “Can ‘Charter Cities’ Change the World? A Q&A With Paul Romer.” Freakonomics
Blog.
Paul
Romer. January 27, 2010 “For Richer, For
Poorer.” Prospect Magazine.
[1] http://www.cgdev.org/files/16352_file_CMP_place_premium_148.pdf
READER COMMENTS
Dan S
Mar 22 2011 at 12:14pm
Is the idea to bribe foreign governments into allowing charter cities to be created? If so, how much money would it take to pull something like that off?
Philo
Mar 22 2011 at 2:33pm
“Frankly, voices like this need less influence on policy, not more.” Doubtful. In the poor countries, the voices that *have* been influencing policy have produced . . . *poverty*! The voice of the people might not push the government toward improvement, but why think it would make things *worse*?
Philo
Mar 22 2011 at 2:40pm
“[T]he paths the Gates Foundation currently intends to pursue sound worse than doing nothing.” It’s sad to see Gates’s and Buffett’s billions wasted, when the former might have funded promising technological start-ups and the latter profitable non-technology companies. If only these men had resisted the philanthropic temptation–the temptation to cast themselves as Great White Fathers.
Jameson Burt
Mar 22 2011 at 2:43pm
To emulate the success of Hong Kong by New-City,
prevent the adjacent country from exporting to anywhere but New-City,
so the New-City population leverages 5 million people to 1 billion people.
If India could be prevented from increasing exports
except through New-City, then any increased product of India’s
1 billion people funneled through New-City;
surprise, New-City becomes a success that we can ascribe
to whatever political/economic system runs New-City.
Macao, China, ran independently rather like Hong Kong,
though for a few more years,
reducing itself to gambling and cheap food to quickly spit out,
so no-one touts Hong Kong’s sister Macau as successful.
I find the more limited success of Singapore quintessential.
Singapore seeks better government,
so it gets many technocrats from other countries.
It’s government discusses enterprise categories to support.
The single city of Singapore even has a better military
than nearby countries.
But really.
Look at successful businesses throughout southeast Asia
and parts of Africa.
Increase Chinese immigration to any city
in these places (Malaysia, Indonesia, Africa)
and magically the city increases in prosperity.
The Chinese immigrant’s success is so great that
their host country often handicaps them;
eg, Singapore limits their entrance to colleges.
To really increase the success
of Biloxi, Mississippi,
do as Mississippi did to 1 million of its residents 50 years ago
— expel them,
but now replace them with Chinese: walla, a prosperous town.
Saracen
Mar 22 2011 at 4:49pm
Strong piece. Bryan predictably omits the biggest reason for open borders’ unpopularity–the empirical fact that we don’t know how to prevent it from trashing First World living standards, if LA is any guide–but this fact only strengthens the case for charter cities, raising it from second-best to first-best solution.
Maniel
Mar 22 2011 at 5:14pm
Nice idea! Do you think it would work in the USA? No public-sector unions allowed, of course.
Blake
Mar 22 2011 at 6:12pm
Who would pay for and set up sewage, roads, law enforcement, courts, etc? Doesn’t this assume anarcho-capitalism is a viable system?
fender
Mar 22 2011 at 6:33pm
I want to point on something a little bit of the topic, about which you mentioned here and what was recently written here:
http://mises.pl/blog/2011/03/21/wisniewski-metafora-zniszczonej-elektrowni/ – namely, that according to vulgar experience, there is virtually no relationship between economic literacy and advocating for the market. The author from the link illustrates this by the common fallacy of the broken window made by economists writing in the context of recent Japan catastrophe, that it would stimulate economic growth. We can imagine that common people don’t think so (unless they heard a bad economist…).
Michael Strong
Mar 22 2011 at 8:13pm
Superb letter, Bryan.
Tom West
Mar 22 2011 at 9:20pm
Unfortunately, I think a prime factor for HK’s success was the presumed British willingness to go to war for it.
I suspect that unless the Bill Gates bought an aircraft carrier and threatened to obliterate the country that broke their “charter city” agreement, no charter city would have the security that is needed for long term prosperity.
After all, how many of us would voluntarily cede all jurisdiction over one part of our house, no matter how unused. And how likely, once that ceded portion became valuable, would our descendants be willing to voluntarily keep their hands off of it, when all law indicates that it is their’s to dispose of as they wish.
Evan
Mar 23 2011 at 12:06am
The market solved this problem decades ago through a device called “property values.” This system makes it more expensive to live in some places in others, automatically segregating poor low-IQ people from middle-class high-IQ people by making it too expensive for them to live in the same place.
As an example, I live in a nice area only fifty miles from a large city inhabited by the sort of people that, if they lived in another country, closed borders types would want to keep out at all costs. These people are citizens of the same country I am, so they are free to move where they wish. If I thought the same way closed border types did, I would be terrified that they will move to my area and start committing crimes and doing all the other undesirable stuff. However, the free market naturally prevents them from coming to the area because it is too expensive to live and commute from there, so I’m not worried at all.
So yeah, immigration is still best, but charter cities really seem worth a try too.
That’s an excellent point, but the housing metaphor you use is kind of inappropriate. Isn’t ceding jurisdiction over part of your house called “renting it out?” Aren’t the heirs of landlords bound by rental agreements?
However, your larger point stands, because being a citizen or leader of a country isn’t really much like being owner of a house. I could see some popular movement to loot a charter city, but I can also see a few ways to counter it:
-Make charter cities essential to the operation of powerful business interests that have influence in other parts of the country as well. Then they’ll lobby against looting it.
-I assume the city would still pay some taxes to the host country, if it makes enough money maybe the taxes will be profitable enough that it will be a “kill the goose” scenario.
Tom West
Mar 23 2011 at 1:45am
Isn’t ceding jurisdiction over part of your house called “renting it out?” Aren’t the heirs of landlords bound by rental agreements?
What I was trying to convey is that there is no higher authority than a country with respect to its own internal affairs (at least until it starts killing large numbers of its own citizens). i.e. there is no higher authority for a charter city to appeal to if a country decides to revoke its charter.
The example I had in mind was more of letting your friend have a decrepit room in your house. Years later your friend has really fixed up the room, but all your son, who now owns the place after your demise, sees is someone staying in the nicest room in the house for free. It’s not a situation that’s going to last long…
Your ideas for trying to avoid that are about a charter city’s best hope. The other thing is that a successful charter city is a *threat* to the continued reign of a kleptocrat. You’ll have to give him a good reason to allow something that could cost him his job (or life) to continue to exist.
Daniel Klein
Mar 23 2011 at 3:57am
Outstanding.
Saracen
Mar 23 2011 at 4:31am
As an example, I live in a nice area only fifty miles from a large city inhabited by the sort of people that, if they lived in another country, closed borders types would want to keep out at all costs. These people are citizens of the same country I am, so they are free to move where they wish. If I thought the same way closed border types did, I would be terrified that they will move to my area and start committing crimes and doing all the other undesirable stuff. However, the free market naturally prevents them from coming to the area because it is too expensive to live and commute from there, so I’m not worried at all.
Ever heard of “white flight”? I don’t see how you can argue that all the affected families wouldn’t have been happier if the influx of poor low-IQ people that compelled them to move didn’t happen. Granted, slavery rather than low-IQ immigration was the original source of this problem; but there is no good reason to make the problem even worse.
Yes, you can pay more and more to insulate yourself, and it’ll usually work. But what happens if a disaster strikes–would you rather be in a rich part of New Orleans, or a poor part of northern Japan? Your system is brittle in numerous ways that are not reflected in the mathematical model you’re implicitly using. (See e.g. Robert Putnam’s work on diversity.)
By the way, I say this as a nonwhite immigrant. I accept a risk of expulsion in the event of nativist overreaction, since your favored policy of overshooting in the other direction is nearly guaranteed to make this country not worth living in any more.
Giuseppe
Mar 23 2011 at 9:08am
Great letter. The lessons of Hong Kong and Singapore have not been effectively incorporated into development thinking and it is great to see the Charter Cities project trying to build upon their experience. Do you know if Gates Foundation releases any information on why they chose to pass up an opportunity? I would be very interested to hear the counter arguments.
EclectEcon
Mar 23 2011 at 11:23am
I recommend that the Gates Foundation buy up sizable chunks of Detroit and build a charter city there. The population of Detroit has dwindled to pre-1910 levels and there are blocks and blocks that are abandoned.
Usems
Mar 23 2011 at 3:59pm
Powerful case. Thanks Prof Caplan.
D Carnes
Apr 14 2011 at 7:35pm
The example I had in mind was more of letting your friend have a decrepit room in your house. Years later your friend has really fixed up the room, but all your son, who now owns the place after your demise, sees is someone staying in the nicest room in the house for free. It’s not a situation that’s going to last long…
If you read through the Charter Cities website, Paul Romer actually does address this very real threat by noting that a country or group of countries would have to agree to protect the Charter City. Hong Kong had the British umbrella; a new city could have Canada, the UN, the EU, etc (he argues the US wouldn’t be a good choice – too much geopolitical baggage).
I think the Gates Foundation is one of the few entities that could actually get a CC formed – they seem to have the money, the connections, the media, and the know-how to get it done right.
Comments are closed.