Emily Skarbek has already offered very sound thoughts on Brexit – and David Henderson and Scott Sumner (as well as David Beckworth) are debating whether Brexit constitutes a monetary shock.
I would just like to build on the point Emily was making: that is, “Trade policy that is crafted in the next few years will be crucial to the economic impact of Brexit”.
Indeed, when push comes to shove, it will all be about the sort of trade policy the “Brexited” UK will pursue. It has been pointed out, for example here, that, for all the free trade rhetoric on the Leave side,
The pro-Brexit forces are correct that the EU has a strongly protectionist tilt towards the world outside the union. Although its 28 nations can exchange goods and services free of tariffs inside the trading bloc, the EU is a walled expanse that imposes duties on most of what enters from the U.S., China, and the rest of the non-EU world. The tariffs are especially high on manufactured products and food, averaging from 10%-to-20%.
(…) Yet Johnson and other pro-Brexit leaders have never suggested eliminating or even reducing current EU duties. In fact, Johnson recently stated that leaving the EU would allow the UK to raise duties on steel imports to keep jobs in the beleaguered industry in Wales and Northern England. Toyota, GM, and other big automakers in the U.K. do a thriving export business with the rest of Europe. They’re adamantly opposed to a Brexit that would force them to pay 10% tariffs on the cars they sell in France or Germany. And if the U.K. exits, does anyone believe it wouldn’t impose duties at least that high on imports from Japan or Korea to shield an industry employing 800,000?
If the U.K. exits, it would be forced to pay tariffs, often heavy ones, on the 45% of its exports sold in the EU. Yet it’s likely to impose the same duties, or even higher barriers, to support cars, agriculture and a host of big industries, and get no benefit at all from the lower prices prevailing outside the EU.
On the top of that, by leaving, the UK will be in no position to attempt to influence European legislation, though it will still be affected by it profoundly, when it comes for example to the setting of standards and various product regulations, precisely because EU countries are a very important trading partner.
The prevalent comments in the EU are now stressing the importance of expedited negotiations with the UK, and seem to be rooted in a retaliatory understanding of the future trade deal. As always, people tend to forget that free trade is beneficial for all parties. Tariffs won’t just hurt, say, Rolls Royce’s exports to France, but also those very French customers that may want to buy a Rolls Royce first and foremost.
The most dangerous effect of Brexit, as seen from Brussels, is that it might trigger a domino effect – or at least suggest to some countries that real benefits can be gained by entering in tougher negotiations with the EU leadership for whatever special conditions they may want to negotiate. Brexit is a precedent (*).
So, even if member states’ own interest would suggest negotiations should reach a free trade agreement as smoothly as possible (think about Italy, where roughly speaking 7% of exports is with the UK), EU negotiators may try, perceiving it as their own self-interest, to produce a different outcome. A single market should remain far superior, in terms of lower transaction costs, to whatever trade agreement may be reached. And yet perhaps negotiators may aim to “teach a lesson”, besides this point. Handersblatt reports that Germany’s Minister of Finance, Wolfgang Schäuble, is himself carefully weighing the alternatives.
So, what should Boris Johnson or Theresa May, or whoever is going to be the next prime minister, do? Perhaps it is time to be bold: unilateral free trade, at least with EU member countries. Sure, unilateral free trade is very unpopular. To the best of my knowledge, in recent years only Georgia moved in that direction, as “since 2006, it implemented basic free trade unilaterally for its imports from the whole of the world, such that its average industrial tariff is now 0.3%, compared with 4.6% for the EU. But its reforms have gone far deeper still, unilaterally opening all its markets to foreign direct investment and recognizing the technical standards for imports from all OECD countries, including the EU”.
But if the new British prime minister want to puzzle and indeed shock its European counterparts, this may well be the best option. Go ahead and zero tariffs on imports coming from the EU. It might well be one of those very few choices that could prove to be economically beneficially in the long run, not least because it will minimize the problem of capture by special interest groups when it comes to trade policy. But it may prove to be expedient from a political perspective too. As the government should run through the Houses its proposed “interpretation” of the vote (which was, after all, a consultative referendum), open support for free trade may help, in the short run, to restore peace and harmony among the Tories. On top of this, it might give the UK a strong card in negotiations with the EU, making retaliatory attempts hard to “sell” to the public.
(*) A more interesting precedent would be if Brexit were to be followed by another Scottish referendum, this time won by the independence front. The Scots may prefer to stay with the EU than keeping the United Kingdom united. The EU so far has been lukewarm with secessionist movements. But if they welcome the Scots in, what about the Catalans? Watch out for some interesting developments.
READER COMMENTS
Matthew Moore
Jun 28 2016 at 7:59am
The majority of regulations affecting the UK are now set by global bodies, and then implemented by the EU ( eg Basel and many UN initiatives). Currently the UK has no chair at these discussions, but has instead been ‘expertly’ ‘represented’ by the EU.
So, the argument about losing influence is not clear cut.
The schizophrenic Leave campaign advocated both cutting many new free trade deals and implementing specific protectionist policies. This was to target both wings of the movement.
However, it looks very likely that a Conservative government will be leading, which is good for free trade
Benjamin R Kennedy
Jun 28 2016 at 10:55am
“As always, people tend to forget that free trade is beneficial for all parties.”
Except for people that lose their jobs and livelihoods, or have a reasonable fear of that happening? Always glossing over these negative consequences is why we have Trumpism/Brexit in the first place
John Alexander Thacker
Jun 28 2016 at 7:45pm
Scotland would like to stay within Europe (and perhaps British independence will make the EU more likely to accept Scotland than Scotland breaking off from an existing member as the case will be somewhat different than Flanders or Catalonia). However, if the EU decides to “teach a lesson” by having high EU tariff barriers with the rest of the UK, that’s bad for Scotland. The rest of the UK is Scotland’s largest trading partner, and a natural trading partner. If Scotland can only remain in Europe by having high tariffs with England, that’s bad.
Very true that the responses matter.
Weir
Jun 28 2016 at 10:43pm
Obama’s threat two months ago was to teach a lesson to the Brits, sending them to the back of the queue. (Still better than being under the bus.) Peter Sutherland, chairman of Goldman Sachs for twenty years, was even more punitive: “Somehow this result must be overturned.”
An EU that doesn’t punish Europeans with tariffs would be an EU worth belonging to. Alain Juppe is talking about reform. Jean-Claude Juncker is talking business as usual: “The usual reflex is for the finger to be pointed at Brussels. Yet in this case, that is completely wrong: the referendum was called by the British Prime Minister and not by the European Parliament, the Commission or the European Council.” He thinks the referendum was the problem.
The EU could reform itself, and choose free trade, instead of their customs union. They built a wall against Africa and Asia and America and India and Australia, and call it free trade.
The UK could reform itself. An immigrant from Australia is already subject to what in Britain everyone keeps calling “an Australian-style points based system.” This policy, which is Cameron’s policy for everyone outside the EU, is according to Cameron an absolutely crazy policy for people coming from Europe.
But a British immigration policy is bound to be more popular than a policy imposed on it by Juncker. (Which is itself a policy imposed on him by the entrepreneurial ferry captains on the Mediterranean who, in turn, have no say over the violent storms and rough seas that sometimes drown their customers.)
A British trade policy already exists: The Conservative PM Robert Peel won the British parliament over to it in 1846, democratically, within Britain.
John T Kennedy
Jun 29 2016 at 3:11pm
Alberto,
Bravo! But isn’t unilateral laissez faire the best trade poicy for *every* nation?
And why do I so seldom hear economists say so?
JohnW
Jul 4 2016 at 3:15pm
France has a veto on agriculture legislation – unilateral free trade with the Commonwealth and beyond is a no-brainer.
[Incorrectly coded link removed–Econlib Ed.]
Stuart Holliday
Jul 25 2016 at 1:54pm
Unilateral laissez fair is not the best policy for several reasons. In markets where there is a natural global monopoly, it may lead to a net loss for the country if it doesn’t have the winning company. There are strategic reasons why I.e. self sufficiency for food is desirable, and possibly for other industries associated with defence or energy. Game theory shows that acting unilaterally is not always the best. Political shortsightedness is also a factor.
Comments are closed.