The US economy has never had a soft landing. It is possible that we are about to have one. If so, it will likely be due to the fact that a massive surge in immigration has provided a big soft pillow for the economy to land on.
[Note: I will not address the question of whether this immigration is good in any overall sense, just the impact on the macroeconomy.]
Some of the recent economic data is about as bizarre as I’ve ever seen:
Q2 NGDP up 5.2% annual rate, 5.8% over 12 months
Q2 RGDP up 2.8% annual rate, 3.1% over 12 months
And yet the household survey suggests that fewer that 200,000 net new jobs have been created over the past 12 months. That makes no sense. The real GDP data says we are in a major boom, and the household survey of employment suggests we are barely avoiding a recession. What gives?
The answer seems to be immigration. The household survey is not picking up the surge in immigration, many of whom are undocumented. But the government’s payroll survey of employment is picking up the immigrants, and shows a very large 2.6 million increase (1.67%) in net new jobs over the past 12 months. That data is roughly what you’d expect with the 3.1% RGDP growth.
The payroll survey has always been viewed as more accurate than the household survey for short run changes in employment, but I don’t ever recall seeing such a huge discrepancy. This discrepancy coincides with a historically large surge in immigration.
Yesterday, Bill Dudley had a Bloomberg piece suggesting that “The Fed Needs To Cut Rates Now”. Here are a few of his arguments:
Slower growth, in turn, means fewer jobs. The household employment survey shows just 195,000 added over the past 12 months. The ratio of unfilled jobs to unemployed workers, at 1.2, is back where it was before the pandemic.
Most troubling, the three-month average unemployment rate is up 0.43 percentage point from its low point in the prior 12 months — very close to the 0.5 threshold that, as identified by the Sahm Rule, has invariably signaled a US recession.
As I suggested, I think the household figures are simply wrong. I am a big fan of Sahm’s Rule, however, and indeed once developed a cruder version of this idea in an old blog post. But in most cases, rising unemployment is triggered by a fall in labor demand. In this case, a huge surge in labor supply seems to explain the uptick in unemployment (to a rate that is still low in absolute terms.) Nonetheless, I would be concerned if unemployment rose up to 4.5%.
I do not offer opinions on where the Fed should set interest rates. But I see no need for the Fed to ease monetary policy, as NGDP growth is still excessive, even accounting for labor force growth. So monetary policy is not currently too tight, at least based on recent macro data and the implied predictions in various asset markets (especially stocks.)
Please do not take this as a statement that I am opposed to lower interest rates. It is likely (but not certain) that interest rates will have to fall at some point over the next 12 months, if only to keep the stance of monetary policy roughly neutral. Again, interest rates are not monetary policy.
A Fed anti-inflation program during a period of low unemployment normally produces a recession. Not usually, it always produces a recession within a few years. If it doesn’t happen this time, it will be our first soft landing.
[Note: The media often applies the term “soft landing” to something like the mid-1990s, a period of rising and then falling interest rates with no recession. I am using the term for a sustained period of cyclically low unemployment without rising inflation. Say at least three years. We’ve never had that, although without Covid we probably would have. We are about 9 months away from me declaring this to be America’s first soft landing. (Will Trump or Harris be able to take credit?)]
If we do achieve this sort of result (which is not that uncommon in other countries), we need to consider how it happened. In my view, it would be due to a mix of luck and skill. The skill would be the Fed’s ability to slow NGDP growth at a steady rate, without overshooting in either direction. In retrospect, money clearly should have been tighter in 2022 and 2023, as there was an outright labor shortage. But it’s hard to be too critical when they seem to have inflation moving in the right direction, albeit too slowly. On the other hand, I am extremely critical of the Fed’s highly inflationary policy of 2021-22.
The luck part is the surge in immigration. Consider the 5.8% NGDP growth over the past year. Prior to Covid, the Fed estimated the economy’s trend rate of growth at 1.8%. Thus you’d expect 5.8% NGDP growth to deliver roughly 4% inflation. If inflation were still that high, the Fed would be under pressure to slam on the breaks, risking recession. Instead, 12-month PCE inflation is down to 2.6%, mostly due to the fast growth in RGDP, caused by the surge in employment. With inflation getting close to the 2% target, the Fed believes it can afford to be patient.
I would encourage people to be wary of pundits warning that money is too tight. Both inflation and NGDP growth are still excessive. Anecdotes about this or that sector of the economy don’t tell the whole story—the overall economy is still booming and the markets are optimistic. I don’t see persuasive evidence that money is too tight.
PS. Also be skeptical of people who say “Inflation would be only X is we adjusted for Y”. NGDP confirms that underlying inflation is still too high. Cherry-pickers want to only throw out the misleading data points that help their argument, not the misleading data points that hurt their argument.
READER COMMENTS
David Seltzer
Jul 25 2024 at 5:23pm
Scott: “In this case, a huge surge in labor supply seems to explain the uptick in unemployment (to a rate that is still low in absolute terms.)” I’m still feeling my way through Econ 101. If the labor supply curve moves down and to the right, wouldn’t employment increase? Wouldn’t the decrease in the price of labor coincide with an increase in quantity of labor demanded if the price of labor is elastic? What am I missing? Thanks.
Scott Sumner
Jul 25 2024 at 6:31pm
I would expect a sudden rise in labor supply to increase both employment and unemployment.
Andrew_FL
Jul 26 2024 at 10:38am
In that case the effect on the unemployment rate is ambiguous
Scott Sumner
Jul 27 2024 at 11:45am
Technically yes, but in practice it would likely rise slightly.
andrew weintraub
Jul 25 2024 at 9:41pm
Is it possible that the surge in immigration makes wages more flexible, especially in a downward direction, and particularly among low skilled workers, so that unemployment will not rise as much or as rapidly as it would if wages were more “sticky”?
Scott Sumner
Jul 26 2024 at 8:36pm
Yes, that’s possible.
Craig
Jul 25 2024 at 10:23pm
The household survey is not picking up the surge in immigration, many of whom are undocumented. But the government’s payroll survey of employment is picking up the immigrants.
Maybe you are correct on this, but why? I mean, I actually received a link on my cell phone to answer the Household Survey, so I have to think illegal immigrants would get the link. I would suspect the propensity to answer the survey might be much lower. Indeed I would expect a citizen on unemployment working for cash under the table to be less likely to answer it or to even answer that he is unemployed. But why wouldn’t an establishment/business answering the Establishment Survey also be reluctant to be forthcoming about illegal hiring? That can include citizens and permanent residents as well. One final point is that Establishment Survey is ‘nonfarm’ payrolls and HH does include farm workers and while not all illegal aliens are farm workers, the migrant farm worker is a cliche.
Nevertheless, I have pondered the wedge between HH and Establishment surveys and have seen this:
“The most obvious source of error would be its birth-death model for incorporating the impact of new firms and firms going out of business.” — https://cepr.net/job-growth-is-the-household-or-establishment-survey-right/
My hypothesis is that remote workers working multiple jobs at the same time are probably not likely to answer the HH survey, but the establishments they work for will report them. I’m seeing something along the lines of 10-15% of the workforce is remote? And I have read that 80% of remote workers have more than one job. https://www.hcamag.com/us/specialization/employee-engagement/how-many-remote-workers-have-two-jobs/435607
Its not the same as somebody at a factory needing a couple extra bucks and cutting lawns on the weekend, this is straight up working for two employers at the very same time. Sure, some will answer it, but I could envision some getting such a survey link on their phones and suspecting some kind of trap and just deleting the message.
Scott Sumner
Jul 25 2024 at 11:40pm
Yes, there are many possibilities. Note that many of the undocumented workers are legally allowed to work while their asylum claims are processed, which takes years.
I put a lot of weight on the strong RGDP growth—the big employment gains seem real. And lots of the new jobs are in things like restaurants, hotels, hospitals, where it’s harder to do two full time jobs at the same time.
Matthias
Jul 26 2024 at 7:01am
One possible mechanism is that undocumented migrants are entering the labour force at the ‘bottom’.
But that probably also means that this pushes up locals into the more productive formal parts of the economy, where the employers survey is also more likely to see them.
Rodrigo
Jul 25 2024 at 10:55pm
Professor,
cannot argue that immigration has helped, but to say, today, that markets are optimistic is a bit of a stretch given we are about to be down 10%, vix is up, in very short period of time. Many factors at play, could be a Trump presidency would counteract the very thing you believe is holding up the economy or his stance on semis or tariffs, or simple fact he is a criminal/not very smart, but today and last couple of weeks, markets have definitely not been optimist about anything. More likely about to give me a stroke!
Scott Sumner
Jul 25 2024 at 11:42pm
Stocks are far higher than a year ago, day to day fluctuations are of minor importance.
BC
Jul 25 2024 at 11:37pm
I’ve also heard the media define a soft landing as the Fed getting back to its inflation target without causing a recession. I guess the “landing” refers to inflation returning to target and the “soft” to no recession. Did that happen in the 1990s?
Scott Sumner
Jul 25 2024 at 11:44pm
There was a recession in 1990-91, as the Fed brought inflation down to 2%. The economy didn’t “land” to low unemployment until the late 1990s, and a recession soon followed.
But yes, there are other possible definitions.
BC
Jul 25 2024 at 11:53pm
Wouldn’t the main determinant of a soft landing be whether the market finds the Fed’s inflation target credible? If the market expects the Fed to bring inflation back to target, then if and when it does, actual inflation will match expected inflation. Hence, no recession. On the other hand, if the market doesn’t expect the Fed to achieve its target, then if and when it does, that would be a negative inflation shock (actual inflation less than expected). Hence, recession.
Inflation markets for the last few years have been predicting that inflation would return to the 2.0-2.5% range. If anything, one could argue that inflation has dropped more slowly than expected. (Hard to tell because the shortest TIPS data I have had has been for 5-yr TIPS.) Maybe, the decade of low inflation between the Great Recession and Covid has paid off. The market may have learned that the Fed is credible about bringing inflation down. Were wage contracts over the last few years set assuming 2% long run inflation or something higher?
Scott Sumner
Jul 26 2024 at 11:50am
Good comment, but as far as I can tell labor contracts have been running a bit higher than what you’d expect with 2% inflation. But we are making progress there as well.
TMC
Jul 26 2024 at 3:05pm
I’ve seen comments that these numbers are driven by loss of full time jobs, but an increase in part time jobs. Also many of the jobs created are people getting second jobs. I’ve never been surveyed, so I don’t know how they cover it.
spencer
Jul 26 2024 at 4:49pm
R-gDp was up because short-term money flows are up. It has peaked.
There is a narrow window in which to lower policy rates. Next year the rate-of-change in long-term money flows will be working against the FED.
Kevin
Jul 26 2024 at 7:31pm
Hi Scott!
I am wondering why you want ngdp back on trend faster rather than slower. Is it just because inflation distorts capital gains taxes? Or because it hurts the Fed’s credibility? I understand the value of speed when monetary policy is worsening unemployment, but if it’s just creating extra inflation, why fix it immediately? Why not just head in the right direction? I know the best policy is stable ngdp growth, but I guess I’m just curious why you’re passionate about it instead of patient. I know it doesn’t represent your ideal regime, but the Fed doesn’t do that no matter what, even if they happened to do it on accident. Do you see what I’m getting at? Not a gotcha, just curious since I’ve seen this position/frustration in many of your posts across both blogs.
I continue to love your posts, and I hope all is well!
Scott Sumner
Jul 26 2024 at 8:44pm
The longer it takes to bring down inflation, the greater the risk that doing so will lead to a recession. That seems to me to be one lesson of the 1960s and 1970s. It turns out that the policy “doves” actually made the business cycle worse. In addition, it seems to me that 2022 was a missed opportunity. The Fed could have brought down inflation without a significant cost in terms of high unemployment (due to the labor shortage), and they missed their chance. That made their job harder in 2023.
To be clear, I think their current policy stance is at least defensible, so my criticism has more to do with past decisions, especially the decision to make FAIT asymmetric. In general, I fear that a Fed regime that is highly discretionary will lead to more business cycle instability than a more rigorous rule such as NGDPLT.
Thomas L Hutcheson
Jul 27 2024 at 5:42pm
I thought the missed opportunity (to start raising the EFFR) was in late 2021, when TIPS first went above target. What were you looking at to see the missed opportunity in 2022 and what should te Fed have done when?
Todd Ramsey
Jul 27 2024 at 9:28am
Under a NGDPLT regime, would the targets need to consider the expected change in population due to immigration?
Would targeting a 4% annual increase in NGDP constrain economic growth if population increased 2% annually? What if population increased 4% annually? I know that’s not likely, it’s just an example to help me understand.
Scott Sumner
Jul 27 2024 at 11:43am
Yes, ideally the target would be in per capita terms. Or per working age population.
Thomas L Hutcheson
Jul 27 2024 at 5:59pm
On the larger point I do not understand how immigration makes the Fed’s ability to achieve its FAIT or NGDP target easier? With an NGDP target, does unexpected immigration not make real GDP harder to predict and so harder to control nominal GDP to hit a NGDP target? Or even if immigration was correctly expected, how does that not just leave the target hitting task the same, neither harder nor easier?
Lorenzo from Oz
Aug 9 2024 at 11:02pm
And for amusement value, there is Peter Zeihan saying lots of border crossings keep down inflation.
https://youtu.be/f1tP9Ciz7k8?si=nUanu2lQ5h37Xbue
That no doubt “explains” why very-little-migration-Japan had prolonged deflation problems … oh, wait.
It is up there with historians “explaining” that population growth explains the Price Revolution from the late C15th to early C18th. Just like massive population growth “explains” why British prices had almost no net change from 1822 to 1913 .. oh, wait.But lots of extra people can certainly push demand up. As Australia has benefited from, which explains why Australian inflation has been so high … oh wait.
Comments are closed.