Someone asked recently what would change as a result of the world being plunged into a trade war by the Rose Garden tariffs. I quipped that either Adam Smith would be proved wrong or we’d all get poorer. (This is also true of the scaled-back tariffs, which still leave American tariffs higher than they’ve been in a century.)
In response, as sometimes happens, they brought up Adam Smith’s arguments for tariffs. These arguments come from Book 4, Chapter 2 of Wealth of Nations. They’re a red herring, as we’ll see. But let’s look at how they apply.
There are two instances in which Smith says you can always justify managing trade, and two cases in which managing trade can’t be automatically condemned. Restrictions on imports can always be justified (1) in shipping because it’s tied to military defence, and (2) by taxing imports at the same rate that domestic goods are taxed to create a level playing field. Trade restrictions shouldn’t be automatically condemned when (A) they are retaliatory tariffs, or (B) free trade is being phased in.
So what’s the big deal? Retaliatory tariffs are right there in the list. Why would the Rose Garden tariffs vex Adam Smith?
Smith is very specific about when retaliatory tariffs are appropriate. “There may be good policy in retaliations of this kind, when there is a probability that they will procure the repeal of the high duties or prohibitions complained of.” (IV.ii.39) In other words, retaliatory tariffs are good if they secure freer trade. Israel’s elimination of tariffs against the United States did not spare them. When Vietnam and the European Union offered to eliminate all tariffs, the administration rejected these offers as insufficient. If these were meant to be retaliatory tariffs, they’ve failed.
But the Rose Garden tariffs were never retaliatory. They were not based on how much other countries tariff the United States. They are not even based on estimates of non-tariff barriers. The White House confirmed that the method used to calculate the tariffs was the trade deficit divided by U.S. imports from that country, then divided again by 2 (Unless a country does not run a trade deficit with the United States, in which case the tariff was set to 10%).
So it’s not about retaliation, but—at best—a negative trade balance. And we all know what Adam Smith said about the balance of trade, right?
But anyway, Adam Smith’s arguments about tariffs are a red herring if we want to know what Adam Smith would think of these tariffs.
The effect of the tariff announcement in the Rose Garden was not simply to raise the price of international trade. As Thomas Sowell observed, the tariff announcement also introduced uncertainty that makes foreign investment and globally integrated supply chains more vulnerable—more risky—at the same time as the tariffs themselves make international trade more expensive. The overall effect of these policies is the effect of all trade restrictions: they effectively shrink the global market. Exchanges that would otherwise make sense become more expensive and they don’t happen.
Adam Smith’s core economic insight, the one from which all other arguments in the Wealth of Nations follows, is that the wealth of nations is a product of the division of labour (Book 1, Chapter 1), of cooperation facilitated by our natural propensity to truck, barter, and exchange (Book 1, Chapter 2). The division of labour is limited by how many people we can divide labour between, what Smith calls the “extent of the market” (Book 1, Chapter 3).
If we will not be poorer because the tariff announcement in the Rose Garden shrunk the number of potential trades, and with them the extent of the market, then the division of labour is not the source of the wealth of nations. If the Rose Garden tariffs won’t make us all poorer, then Adam Smith was wrong about everything.
If Smith was wrong about everything, who cares when he says tariffs are good?
Related content:
CEE Entries: Protectionism, Mercantilism
WealthofTweets: Book 4, Chapter 2
WealthOfTweets: Book 4 Chapter 3
Jon Murphy, The Political Problem of Tariffs
READER COMMENTS
Ahmed Fares
Apr 10 2025 at 4:59pm
Adam Smith wrote that division of labor would make a people rich. He also wrote that it would make them stupid.
john hare
Apr 11 2025 at 4:23am
I had not seen this before. What I have seen in construction is that we try to simplify many of the procedures such that people that don’t try to think can still get a job done. I hadn’t thought of the procedures themselves as causing the reluctance to think out the issues.
It is a standing company joke that “John will figure it out” due to many people waiting on me for answers. Not just employees, but job superintendents and contractor customers as well. Distressing sometimes as I am aware of my own limitations when trying to solve issues that are rightfully Someone Else’s’ Problem (SEP).
Warren Platts
Apr 13 2025 at 8:30am
Smith, I will give him credit: when John Paul Jones of that combined French and American squadron circled around Scotland, Smith’s coast guard scared them off. Then the real battle happened off the east coast of England..
Mactoul
Apr 11 2025 at 3:10am
http://www.nytimes.com/2025/04/10/opinion/ross-douthat-interesting-times.html
Warren Platts
Apr 11 2025 at 6:22am
Adam Smith I would describe as a mild protectionist. After all, he was the head Commissioner of Customs in Scotland. His book was a screed against rampant mercantilism. I don’t know why you professional economists can’t see the difference.
Jon Murphy
Apr 11 2025 at 9:13am
Good stuff Janet.
I argue that, hinted at by Smith, when these tariffs (even if initially justifiable) increase the likelihood of war and civil discord, they should likewise be shunned. In the discussion of retalitory tariffs, Smith argues that the Dutch retalitory tariffs on France in response to French tariffs lead to the War of 1672 (see page 467, about the halfway point of paragraph 38). He even denounces the Navigation Acts for their contribution to the American Revolution and weakning the political unity of Great Britain (see page 604-605).
So, I think Smith would also argue these tariffs are bad because of the civil and political discord they sow
Monte
Apr 12 2025 at 1:16am
Yet it seems that our present company of economists are adamantly opposed to tariffs of even this kind. Smith famously advocated for free trade, but he was not an absolutist. Those who are would do better to quote the more doctrinaire Richard Cobden instead:
But this is eschatology, not economics.
*From Cobden’s “I Have a Dream” speech about a world in which free trade is the governing principle.
Jon Murphy
Apr 12 2025 at 6:41am
Yes. For the same reason Smith was opposed to tariffs of that kind. If tariffs result in the reduction of barriers, then they can be useful. But Smith was famously skeptical of the practical use of tariffs for such a purpose. And modern economists are the same way. The evidence indicates tariffs have, at best, limited influence as a negotiation tool for lower trade barriers. Indeed, the experience of the last century indicates they’re more likely to result in a war (trade or otherwise).
One must always remember that there is a difference between a theoretical case and a practical case.
Monte
Apr 12 2025 at 11:16am
He was philosophically, but not unequivocally, opposed. Practically speaking, he felt tariffs could be justified if they had a reasonable chance of inducing freer trade abroad:
Smith accepted, however, that unrestrained free trade between nations was a fantasy:
A capitulation to which Cobden gave no quarter:
To Cobden, free trade was a creed. To Smith, it was simply a preference. That’s why I say absolutists are better represented in their beliefs by Cobden.
Jon Murphy
Apr 12 2025 at 11:07pm
Correct. That “if,” as is described in the paragraph quoted, is a big if.
Which he would be proven wrong about a mere 50 years after his death. Thanks, in part, to Cobden.
I guess I don’t understand this claim. What are you trying to say?
Monte
Apr 13 2025 at 1:51am
What I’m trying to say is that, to Cobden, free trade was a moral conviction. He had an unwavering faith in free trade as a universal truth. Whereas to Smith, free trade was an ideal worth striving for, but subject to practical and political considerations. In other words, Smith saw free trade as a guiding principle.
Monte
Apr 13 2025 at 2:20am
I can’t think of, or find, an instance in history where fully unrestrained free trade took place between nations without some kind of tariff or barrier. Can you provide an example?
Jon Murphy
Apr 13 2025 at 6:00am
For Smith, free trade was a moral imperative too. Free trade was just. Indeed, for that reason, any violations of free trade must be undertaken with the utmost caution as they were inherently unjust.
Jon Murphy
Apr 13 2025 at 8:15am
That’s an impossible standard. There are always barriers to trade, not the least of which are transportation costs.
Free trade is people allowed to exchange goods and capital without preference or undue restraint. Great Britain in the 1800s had such a policy, culminating in the Cobden-Chevalier Treaty of 1860. More recently, you have things like GATT, the WTO, and Hong Kong pre-China rule. Singapore, too, if memory serves.
Warren Platts
Apr 12 2025 at 5:45am
lol! Sad but true..
Warren Platts
Apr 17 2025 at 5:14am
Here is the rest of that quote:
Emphasis added because there can be no better description of President Trump. Let’s let him do his job..
Monte
Apr 17 2025 at 9:50am
Beau ideal! Sort of like maggot therapy in treating wounds that are unresponsive to other forms of treatment.