Nothing New Thing Under the Sun: Prohibition, Drugs and the Iron Law

Some time ago, roughly four years, I began this series on how drug prohibition only serves to create the public health crisis that such policies are supposed to mitigate. Of course, I never intended for such a large period to lapse between my last article and this one, but I suppose it is a nice demonstration of the difference between intentions and outcomes.

As a refresher, our last discussion highlighted how Prohibition-Era laws such as the Harrison and Volstead Acts begat later laws such as the Boggs Act of 1951 and the Narcotics Control Act of 1956, which begat the modern War on Drugs™. Today, we will explore further the parallels between the two regime paradigms, highlighting why the continuing failure of the drug war is inevitable and wholly predictable; a Pygmalion Effect which creates what it forbids.

When the Eighteenth Amendment was passed in 1920, it was widely hailed as a watershed moment that would reduce crime and poverty, absolve the public of paying for prisons and poorhouses, and save the family from the vagaries of drunkenness. Similarly, when President Nixon declared drug addiction Public Enemy Number One in 1971, it was with his 1969 declaration  to Congress that the full forces of government must be marshaled “to cope with this growing menace to the general welfare of the United States.” Again, the nation was told, we would reduce crime and poverty, lower the scope and costs of incarceration, and stamp out a danger to the American family.

It is a vast understatement to say that these assurances were wrong, and even this is underselling the deleterious impact of these policies. Between 1916, four years before Prohibition, and 1929, four years before its repeal, both the number of cases terminated in Federal courts and the number of prisoners remanded from those courts effectively quadrupled. This, of course, led to a concomitant rise in prison spending due to overcrowding, which was a clear indication that the promised decrease in crime wasn’t coming. While proponents of Prohibition proudly proclaimed that the tide of crime had lessened, minor crimes such as vagrancy and public swearing had decreased by 50%, while more serious crimes rose precipitously; property theft by 13.2%, homicide by 16.1% and robbery by 83.3%. The tradeoff here is one between a decrease in misdemeanors likely to result in a fine or a night spent in the local jail, and felonies which greatly increased the population of state and Federal prisons.

Similarly, claims that the War on Drugs™ would reduce crime have proven unjustifiably optimistic at best. In 2020, there were an aggregate 1.1 million arrests made for drug-related offenses, of which the majority were for simple possession (Cohen, Vakharia, Netherland, & Frederique, 2022). As of 2015, the rate of prisoners as a function of the population has grown from 100 per 100,000 in the period before Nixonian drug policy to over 500 per 100,000 (Pfaff, 2015). As a result, the United States has become the world’s largest jailer, both in absolute terms and in rate. According to Miron and Waldock, expenditures related to drug prohibition – including the increase both in prisoners and the number of prisons/jails needed to accommodate them – now equals or exceeds some $41.3 million annually

Despite the increase in crime, prison sentences and the cost of enforcement, Prohibition had more of a shifting effect on alcohol consumption; a thing that is also true of drug consumption patterns under the current regime of criminalization. This shift, the effects of which will be discussed in greater detail in my next segment, is comprised of consumers moving away from a product of lesser potency to one of greater. This phenomenon, known as the Iron Law of Prohibition, is a result of fundamental economic principles; the creation of barriers to both entry and supply creates pressure to minimize volume while simultaneously maximizing profit (Beletsky & Davis, 2017). In effect, bulkier products with a lower degree of potency, such as beer or marijuana, are substituted by more potent, less bulky products that are easier to produce and transport, such as hard liquor and cocaine. While beer and marijuana may still be available on the black market, the price of these items rises relative to their more potent, less bulky alternatives, which tilts demand in favor of the harder stuff.

Despite the rise in crime associated with such illicit activities and the organized institutions that produce the wares, much of the distribution of prohibited items is carried out by small-scale entrepreneurs (Levine & Reinarman, 1991). While many of the headlines tout the defeat of cartels and gangs, the reality is that most of the arrests are those of small-to-mid-tier neighborhood distributors. At any given time, somewhere between 1-2 million individuals are involved in drug distribution within the U.S., while roughly a half million individuals are incarcerated for drug-related activities (Kleiman, Caulkins, & Hawken, 2011). What this means is that the average dealer-distributor spends a year incarcerated for every two to four years they engage in selling. 

A Brief Look at Social Costs

All public policy should be judged by comparing costs to benefits, including costs that are social rather than monetary. While monetary costs are easier to examine – it is a balance sheet problem, after all – social costs are no less important. Between 1973 and 2013, over $1 trillion was spent on drug enforcement in the U.S. alone. Yet, in 2016, Americans spent $150 billion on heroin, methamphetamines, cocaine, and marijuana, which doesn’t even factor in other classes of illicit drugs. Perhaps the most troubling aspect of these sunk opportunity costs is that despite a regime of increasing funding for supply-side enforcement, drug prices have continued to decline over the last four decades.  This isn’t to say that they exist in cost parity with legal substances; their prices are still higher. What it does say is that current policy does little to abate demand.

Moreover, instead of reducing crime, prohibition simply creates more criminals. Everyone involved in the drug market, from supplier to distributor to consumer, is automatically a criminal. Absent the property rights protections and dispute resolution apparatus available via normal legal channels, interested parties must resolve their own conflicts, often leading to violent means. Benson et al. (2001) find that drug enforcement is not associated with a rise in violent crime, but is also correlated with a rise in property crime; not necessarily because those involved in the drug market are committing these property crimes, but because of the opportunity costs associated with shifting resources away from one set of crimes and towards another. 

Just as it was with alcohol during Prohibition, quality control is an issue with illegal drugs. As we discussed earlier, prohibitory laws create incentives to minimize the costs of production and transport while maximizing profit, which in turn trends towards potency as the major concern. Because the product is manufactured by local entrepreneurs, however organized, there are no industry-wide safety standards. Hence, the current issue of heroin laced with fentanyl, for example. This leads to an increase in drug-related overdoses, and other related problems.

These are just a few of the more obvious social costs related to the War on Drugs™.Next, we will take a deeper dive into the issue of social costs.

 

References

Beletsky, L., & Davis, C. S. (2017). Today’s Fentanyl Crisis: Prohibition’s Iron Law, Revisited. International Journal of Drug Policy, 46, 156-159. doi:10.1016/j.drugpo.2017.05.050

Benson, B. L., & Leburn, I. S. (2001). The Impact of Drug Enforcement on Crime: An Investigation of the Opportunity Cost of Police Resources. Journal of Drug Issues, 31(4), 989-1006. doi:10.1177/002204260103100410

Cohen, A., Vakharia, S. P., Netherland, J., & Frederique, K. (2022). How the War on Drugs Impacts Social Determinants of Health Beyond the Criminal Legal System. Annals of Medicine, 54(1), 2024–2038. doi:10.1080/07853890.2022.2100926

Kleiman, M., Caulkins, J. P., & Hawken, A. (2011). Drugs and Drug Policy : What Everyone Needs to Know. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Levine, H. G., & Reinarman, C. (1991). From Prohibition to Regulation: Lessons from Alcohol Policy for Drug Policy. The Milbank Quarterly, 69(3), 461-494. doi:10.2307/3350105

Pfaff, J. F. (2015). The War on Drugs and Prison Growth: Limited Importance, and Limited Legislative Options. Harvard Journal on Legislation, 52, 173-220.

 


Tarnell Brown is an Atlanta based economist and public policy analyst.

READER COMMENTS

Monte
Apr 4 2024 at 12:33pm

My comment may be a bit premature since you’ll be following up with a closer look at the social costs of U.S. drug policy, but I wonder if applying the hedonic calculus to the question of drug policy reform might be constructive?  Of course, we should be circumspect about limiting freedom of choice when using this calculus to design policy, but in this instance, we would be enhancing, not restricting, that freedom.

It’s not yet clear to me if you support legalization or decriminalisation (an important distinction).  Also, is it your position that all drugs fall under this purview, keeping in mind the recent experience of both Portugal and Portland, neither of which stands as a superlative model of reform)?

 

 

.

Tarnell S Brown
Apr 9 2024 at 8:46am

I apologize for the delay in responses. Life has been hectic of late…

Legalization and decriminalization both have their upsides and downsides. Philosophically, I support decriminalization, however, I wouldn’t be angry with legalization. Net improvements are better than no improvements.

I will touch on Portland and Portugal in my concluding article. There are lessons to be learned from both.

 

 

steve
Apr 4 2024 at 2:05pm

I think it pretty clear the War on Drugs has been a net negative. I generally favor legalization but i have serious doubts about the very high potency drugs like fentanyl or even worse the ultra high potency drugs like carfentanyl that even the medical profession is afraid to use. I would rather heroin be legal than those. It is way too easy to accidentally overdose on the highly potent drugs.

Steve

Monte
Apr 4 2024 at 3:56pm

Steve,

As a medical professional,  I’d be interested in your thoughts regarding the legalization of Class A drugs.  I, too, suspect the costs would far outweigh the benefits of such a policy, although I’m strongly in favor of emancipating all non-Class A’s.

steve
Apr 5 2024 at 11:49am

I dont know that you have to be a medical professional, and since it’s really a cost benefit analysis others can do that better than I can. Just as a health issue we would be better off if none of there existed and people didnt have the craving/need to get high. But since you asked, if I were in charge I would keep all of the highly potent narcotics that they recently added to the Class A list illegal. When narcotics are that potent it is very easy to overdose even if you know the dose. The safety margin isn’t that high. Older narcotics like heroin are intrinsically safer and I think most fo their risk comes from being illegal so that you arent really sure what you are getting. Outside of the narcotics drugs like ecstasy arent really that unsafe when taken alone so I would be open to analysis on that and if it looks good legalize it. We manage to live with alcohol.

As an aside there is too much emphasis on using death as the only outcome in these discussions. We not uncommonly end up with people we manage to resuscitate who end up with permanent brain damage and other long term problems.

Steve

AMT
Apr 5 2024 at 12:38pm

Steve, I am just wondering about the point “it is very easy to overdose even if you know the dose.” It seems possible, but quite unlikely to me. I’d expect that the vast majority of overdoses are almost entirely due to not knowing the strength of the product and accidentally taking too much. Even for fentanyl. It seems that the huge spike in overdose deaths is due to fentanyl, but because it is so potent it is far easier to mess up the “production” process. I recall a documentary where the drug dealers were using a blender to cut the product, which apparently did a terrible job of mixing it, leading to huge potency differences. I also recall seeing some warning ad showing the fatal dose of fentanyl which looked like just a few grains of salt. If all the users had access to a consistent product I think overdoses would drop a lot, because the main issue is fentanyl potency is very inconsistent because it is so potent and drug dealers are not super conscientious about quality control…

I will concede it might also be possible that the fatal dose is just much closer to the amount users take to get high for fentanyl than heroin, which would make your point correct. Do you have any sources indicating that? E.g. a fentanyl user “needs” 50mcg to get high but 100mcg would be fatal, while the ratio for heroin is much higher, 100mg vs 400mg. (I just made up those numbers)

steve
Apr 6 2024 at 11:26am

No literature of which I am aware. Kind of hard to do an RCT on fatal OD doses. Anyway, your point is a good one. If people had a better idea of what was in what they are injecting probably fewer would OD. However, the kinetics still worry me. The high potency drugs are generally much more lipophilic so they have a much faster onset. They also bind to receptors much more vigorously. Many, I think it’s still most, overdoses occur with experienced addicts, the ones you would expect to know what they are doing.

However, as a group they actually dont always have especially good judgement and most deaths occur when they also use other drugs along with the narcotic. So with the highly potent narcotics you have people who are already high making judgments about what to use. If they push the dose a bit the onset will be very fast and it’s hard to treat them with narcan. Heroin ODs respond better and faster to narcan than the highly potent narcotics.

Steve

Cyril Morong
Apr 4 2024 at 3:21pm

“According to Miron and Waldock, expenditures related to drug prohibition – including the increase both in prisoners and the number of prisons/jails needed to accommodate them – now equals or exceeds some $41.3 million annually.”

I think that should be $41.3 billion

Tarnell S Brown
Apr 9 2024 at 8:48am

Indeed, it should be billion. Good catch.

Cyril Morong
Apr 4 2024 at 3:35pm

“Benson et al. (2001) find that drug enforcement is not associated with a rise in violent crime, but is also correlated with a rise in property crime; not necessarily because those involved in the drug market are committing these property crimes, but because of the opportunity costs associated with shifting resources away from one set of crimes and towards another. ”

 

Did you mean to say “that drug enforcement is not ONLY associated with a rise in violent crime”?

Tarnell S Brown
Apr 6 2024 at 3:18pm

Yes.

John hare
Apr 4 2024 at 4:49pm

One thing not mentioned as much is the hit to the labor force.   Many of the people dealing or incarcerated are the ones that could be in the work force.    Decades ago there were a lot of people in construction with bad habits.   Can’t hire them now because they can’t pass a drug test required by our insurance companies.

Tarnell S Brown
Apr 9 2024 at 8:55am

Correct. Incarceration has certain effects that impact the socialization of the incarcerated, and removal from the labor force is one of them. There will be more on this in my next segment.

Comments are closed.

RECENT POST

The housing sector in Irvine, California is booming, partly due to an inflow of investment from China. When I ask Chinese acquaintances where the money comes from, they suggest that it is transferred to the US through mysterious channels. Commenter Ahmed Fares directed me to a Daily Mail story that sheds light on one s...

Read More

At EconLog, I often catalogue and criticize government measures that reduce our freedom and hurt our economy. So it's nice when I can report on a recent vote that went the other way: a vote to reduce the role of government in our economy. On Tuesday, April 2, voters in Jackson County, Missouri voted, by 58.1% to 41....

Read More

Some time ago, roughly four years, I began this series on how drug prohibition only serves to create the public health crisis that such policies are supposed to mitigate. Of course, I never intended for such a large period to lapse between my last article and this one, but I suppose it is a nice demonstration of the di...

Read More