A report in the New Yorker (and discussed in an NPR Marketplace segment) discusses restaurant table reservations, showing how third-party sellers are earning money by reserving tables at trending restaurants and reselling them to eager diners. These “hustlers” and “mercenaries” as they have been named (and self-named) might be seen, even by themselves, as jacking up the price for something that would be cheaper otherwise.
However, these are alert entrepreneurs who provide an interesting example of how markets can emerge to solve complex coordination problems. Only restaurants in very high-demand locations like New York City have actually experienced a significant amount of such trading activity. As the New Yorker article quotes about one particularly popular Italian spot, “New Yorkers are risking their lives, begging, bribing, and pleading to get a table at the Italian eatery.”

These restaurant tables are scarce commodities. When price is not used, “begging, bribing, and pleading” are ways that the competition for them will take place. The same is true when prices are controlled for other goods. Traders buy and sell reservations by monitoring reservation sites, booking tables, and placing them up for sale on sites like Appointment Trader. By doing this, they increase the likelihood that the tables at these restaurants are allocated to their most valued uses, i.e. to the diners that value them the most. In other words, they likely are enhancing efficiency.
Most restaurant seating is not allocated by the price mechanism, but on a first-come first-served basis. Even when restaurants take reservations, those are also typically first-come first-served. A diner may not know about or decide to try a trendy new restaurant until the evening prior. In this scenario, without third-party sellers, they might find a months-long wait to get a table reservation.
With third-party sellers, there will be a seat available for them – for a price. In turn, the restaurant seats parties most eager to be there and are likely to spend more on average. Third-party sellers are better off as well as long as the money they earn is greater than the cost of the time they use to troll sites for reservation bookings.
There are likely to be people who are worse off. Pareto improvements are difficult to come by. Perhaps passers-by no longer have much of a chance to grab a table that just happens to be empty at the right moment. If tables listed by third-party sellers don’t sell, restaurants may miss opportunities to seat needed customers. Indeed, some restaurants opt not to list reservations with platforms online and use their own system instead. Overall, it is likely the case that total welfare improves from the existence of third-party sellers where reservations are consistently listed on online platforms.
An interesting question is why restaurants don’t raise the price of tables and reap the extra surplus themselves. In the restaurant industry, products are hugely differentiated from one business to the next. Owners of popular restaurants might be said to have a degree of monopoly power; they have high demand for their product, but they are able to restrict output because they are the sole purveyor of it. There is only one place to get a meal at Tatiana in New York. The monopoly power comes from the fact that that no restaurant can perfectly copy what they have. If the wait for a table is months long, that implies that menu prices could be higher, or that the restaurant could use table-pricing to reap more of the monopoly rents that is available to it.
Most restaurants that are successful and popular enough to have predictably full dining rooms every night likely raise menu prices to some degree to accommodate the higher demand, but it would seem not enough to clear the long wait lists. Third-party sellers arise as a result of this fact. The restaurant has left monopoly rents on the table, so to speak, by not putting a price on reservations. This is either because it is not cost-feasible or because there are countervailing reasons for not doing so. Perhaps the notoriety that comes with long waiting lists and high prices for tables on third-party apps is a more valuable reputational asset for restaurants. Or perhaps having the certainty of a full dining room months in advance is more valuable to restaurant owners.
Lastly, two diners who happen to get a table at the same time through first-come first-served seating are likely to place two different values on getting that table. If the restaurant could give each of them a different surcharge for the privilege of getting a table, it could gain the extra surplus. This leaves third-party sellers to fill the role of such price-discrimination by allowing diners to compete in bidding up the price for the table. The restaurant industry is incredibly vibrant, and it is interesting to explore why markets are emerging to address novel issues within it.
Giorgio Castiglia is the Program Manager for the Project on Competition at the Mercatus Center, and a PhD student in economics at George Mason University.
READER COMMENTS
Jim Glass
Jul 13 2024 at 5:48pm
Reminds me of not really so long ago when season tickets to sports teams started trading game-by-game online, over the objections of many teams and pundits. The market won out quickly enough there.
Also of a restaurant on Wall Street maybe 20 years ago that adopted ‘dynamic pricing’: diners could pay for the meal when ordering it or at the end when done, with the price changing in between by ‘supply and demand’. It got the restaurant a good deal of publicity but the business didn’t last.
Thomas L Hutcheson
Jul 14 2024 at 5:51pm
Another similar issue is when cities “run out” of street parking spaces at certain times and places during a day rather than dynamically price spaces so as to (almost) always have a space avaiable for a driver to occupy.
And this price inflexibility bumps onto another problem. People get accustomed to zero price parking spots in certain areas, say near their houses, and then oppose up zoning of the area because it will create competition for spaces.
And don’t even get me started on mispricing of net CO2 emissions! 🙂
David Seltzer
Jul 14 2024 at 6:47pm
Hustlers, Scalpers and mercenaries. If one values a preferred table where quantity supplied is inelastic, they will pay the mercenary because they want the table more than they want the money. An individual’s subjective preference. If one tries to get tickets for a Springsteen concert or Taylor Swift concert, they can be sold out in minutes if not seconds. Resellers and ticket brokers like StubHub create a secondary market for tickets that buyers don’t use for themselves. Those tickets are traded at multiples of initial ticket prices.
Giorgio Castiglia
Jul 15 2024 at 9:34am
Thanks David. You, including Thomas and Jim above, all make great points about situations where the economics is the same. You mention the secondary concert ticket market, which will be the subject of my next essay in light of the DOJ’s lawsuit against Live Nation, where the market for event tickets features prominently.
Comments are closed.