Consider the market for aluminum and the general tariff of 25% that the US administration has planned to impose on all American importers of this metal starting March 12 (compared to a current tariff of 10% that hits fewer aluminum products and exempts some countries including Canada and Mexico). A very good starting point for a rapid economic analysis is a Wall Street Journal story: Bob Tita, “Tariffs Fracture Aluminum Industry: ‘It’s Going to Cost Me a Lot of Money,’” February 26, 2025. I will add my own questions on some related issues.
The new tariff or tax will hit imported aluminum (primary aluminum from smelters and recycled aluminum, in the form of ingots, slabs, billets, and sows, plus some derivative products such as extrusions) and will, as is typically the case, be totally or mostly paid by the buyers of imported aluminum. Only a small proportion of the global production of aluminum is purchased by Americans, so a reduction in domestic demand following the tariff is unlikely to affect world prices significantly; in other words, foreign aluminum producers will not “eat” the American tariff. American consumers will ultimately pay it in the increased prices of their manufactured goods containing aluminum such as automobiles, windows, and beer cans. This is the more obvious as the new tariff applies to imports from all countries. In fact, the bidding up of the aluminum price started on the American market as soon as the tariff was announced.
Many econometric studies have confirmed these results for the tariffs imposed during Donald Trump’s first term.
Another standard result of economic analysis is that American purchasers of domestically produced aluminum (which covers roughly 40% of the supply on the American market) will also pay the increased tariff. The reason is that no efficient manufacturer of aluminum goods would buy any imported aluminum if it costs more than the domestically produced equivalent. This arbitrage—buying at the lower price and not at the higher—will push up the price of domestic aluminum to the level of imported aluminum. Indeed, this is precisely why domestic aluminum producers favor the tariff: it protects them (like in protectionism) against competition and pushes up the price of their own output. They get a “profit windfall.” After the announcement of the new aluminum tariff, as the WSJ story mentions, “prices for U.S.-made aluminum are rising as well.” (See also the explanations in my post “The Elementary Economics of Tariffs and Protectionism, February 2, 2025.)
The domestic producers of aluminum will benefit to the detriment of the domestic consumers of goods containing aluminum. Domestic manufacturers and exporters of such goods will also be harmed as their profits and the value of their productive assets decrease. Some capital will move to other economic sectors. An official at Tompkins Products, a Detroit manufacturer of parts for automotive transmissions, expresses the same idea when he says that the new tariff “is going to cost me a lot of money that I don’t have.” He will have to reduce his production compared to what it would otherwise have been.
“Producing a ton of primary aluminum,” notes the WSJ, “typically uses more electricity than a single household consumes in an entire year.” One reason for the high cost of aluminum production in America is the high cost of electricity compared to, say, Canada, from where 75% of American consumption of aluminum comes. Electricity accounts for some 40% of the cost of operating a smelter. In other words, American producers do not seem to have a comparative advantage in aluminum production, which implies that sacrificing one (average) housing unit for every ton of aluminum domestically produced is a waste. As usual, the market, that is, the free interaction of hundreds of millions of participants, is incomparably better at effecting these allocation choices than political and bureaucratic processes.
Would foreign (or domestic) firms build new smelters in America, replace previous international competition, and bring domestic prices down from their initial after-tariff level? This is possible but it would take time—at least a decade, the WSJ suggests—especially since electricity production would have to expand. The prospective owners of new American smelters would also need to be reasonably sure that the tariff will not later be reduced or eliminated, undercutting the reason for producing more aluminum in America. In other words, the tariff will create a new constituency against its future reversal. This is an expected economic result: for example, the steel industry, which has been protected off and on for the past hundred and fifty years, still needs protection; similarly, the one-hundred-year-old Jones Act, which protects ship owners (and indirectly shipyards) against foreign competition, has been politically impossible to repeal despite its costs for American shippers and consumers (see the work of Colin Grabow and Scott Lincicome on the Jones Act).
Going much further than the WSJ story, we may also ask, What does liberty have to do with the American aluminum market? At least three related things. First, untrammeled economic freedom would allow American consumers to buy their aluminum-containing goods from the least expensive sources. It would allow American and foreign manufacturers to serve American consumers most efficiently. It would not handicap American producers of aluminum goods for domestic and foreign markets.
Second, the American government should not discriminate, “take sides” in Anthony de Jasay’s terms, among its own citizens (or residents) by favoring domestic aluminum producers against domestic consumers and manufacturers of aluminum goods—for example, favoring American investors in aluminum smelters against American beer drinkers. This idea of a non-discriminatory state (except when required by the very maintenance of a free society) has been a major strand in classical-liberal economics and political philosophy up to and including major contemporary theorists such as James Buchanan, Friedrich Hayek (see the links to my reviews of his Law, Legislation, and Liberty), and Anthony de Jasay.
Third, even if the domestically imposed tariffs were partially or totally paid by foreign exporters, and even if the trade war did not get out of control, we should not, in trade matters, ignore the losses of foreigners. As Nobel economist John Hicks noted in a 1942 article,
The Manchester Liberals believed in Free Trade not only on the ground of Fairness among Englishmen, but also on the ground of Fairness between Englishmen and foreigners. The State, so they held, ought not to discriminate among its own citizens; also it ought not to discriminate between its own citizens and others.
READER COMMENTS
Craig
Feb 28 2025 at 10:58am
“Would foreign (or domestic) firms build new smelters in America, replace previous international competition, and bring domestic prices down from their initial after-tariff level?”
I wonder if they would support protective tariffs being placed on the foreign manufacturers of critical machine tools?
Pierre Lemieux
Feb 28 2025 at 8:31pm
Craig: Probably not!
Mactoul
Mar 1 2025 at 1:51am
The American Founders didn’t think so. They explicitly wrote that the Constitution and the government that it establishes is meant for benefit of their posterity.
Indeed the entire point of having a state is to discriminate between the citizens and the foreigners.
Matthias
Mar 1 2025 at 2:45am
You can discriminate between locals and foreigners without having a state just fine.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 1 2025 at 12:56pm
Matthias: It depends who “you” is. Of course, an individual or a voluntary association of individuals (or their capital) could discriminate against who they want (local or foreigner) without a state. If “you” is the state, however, you cannot discriminate against whom you want if the state does not want discriminate against whom you would want to discriminate against, which probably does not include discrimination against yourself. If the purpose of the state is to discriminate, thus, you, really you may not discriminate (or not discriminate) against who you want.
Jon Murphy
Mar 1 2025 at 10:49am
As a historical matter, that doesn’t seem to be the case. The Discriminatory State appears to be an invention of just the past 100 years or so with the rise of nationalism. This is not to say that there haven’t been governments in the past who do discriminate. Rather, I am disputing your claim that the reason states were created was discrimination. The historical evidence points toward mutual defense and other collective action problems, not discrimination. Rather the opposite, states (and other collectives like city-states) reduced discrimination by breaking down tribal barriers.
Anyway, there’s a larger problem. If the purpose of the state is to discriminate, then the seeds are sown for its destruction. Economies where discrimination is rampant perform worse economically and sow the seeds of distrust, ultimately undermining the very community needed.
Mactoul
Mar 1 2025 at 8:53pm
Mutual defense against whom? Outsiders naturally.
Jon Murphy
Mar 1 2025 at 8:56pm
And insiders.
Knut P. Heen
Mar 7 2025 at 6:50am
Nationalism just replaced religious discrimination which has been rampant in Europe for at least 2000 years. Charlemagne banned trade with non-Christians which probably played an important role for the development of the Viking Age.
Most states were formed as protection rackets by invading tribes. At the beginning of the Viking Age most countries in Europe we know today, consisted of many smaller units. What happened was that some ambitious kings started to conquer weaker neighbors to increase their tax base and power. Iceland was the exception. Iceland was populated by Norwegian men who refused the taxes of the newly formed Norwegian kingdom. A fair share of the women they brought to Iceland were captured Irish women.
Many of the smaller units eventually merged into larger units through marriage. Again, to increase the tax base and the kings power. Germany was not united before 1871.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 1 2025 at 1:03pm
Mactoul: Read Buchanan’s Why I, Too, Am Not a Conservative (or, for that matter, Hayek) who makes a distinction between immigration (or at least citizenship) and trade in goods and services. (This book is a simple, neat, short book.)
By the way, interestingly, de Jasay would say that a reason for not having a state is to be free to discriminate or not (individually, you) against whom you wish.
Thomas L Hutcheson
Mar 2 2025 at 2:31pm
Such discrimination might be an inevitable consequence of having a state, but not its raison d’etre.
Jose Pablo
Mar 3 2025 at 8:01pm
Indeed the entire point of having a state is to discriminate between the citizens and the foreigners.
But does this logic extend to individual states within a country? After all, they are ‘states’ in the literal sense of the word.
Does it apply to cities as well?
One could even argue that the entire point of self-consciousness is to distinguish between oneself and all other individuals.
I must admit that I have a strong bias in favor of myself, but I don’t think that makes me a misanthrope. At least, not yet. Working on it.
Pierre Simard
Mar 1 2025 at 6:34am
Bref, les tarifs de Trump sont essentiellement un instrument politique de concentration des bénéfices et de diffusion des coûts.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 1 2025 at 2:05pm
Pierre: You are right that the explanation by concentrated benefits and diffuse costs is a major factor. But it may not explain everything. Surely, there are more votes and glorification for the ruler in the manufacturing industry than in the tiny unwrought-aluminum industry. And perhaps Trump really believes that tariffs make everybody rich (his abyssal ignorance is a factor), but he probably also believes that “everybody” only includes “the people” and not “the enemies of the people.” Ultimately, what the ruler wants is to favor his most weighty clientèles, which don’t only include rich business owners, PAC contributors, and powerful trade unions.
Pierre Simard
Mar 3 2025 at 8:08am
Traduction par ChatGPT de mes notes sur Trump. Une perspective essentiellement Public Choice. (Chat GPT a même fait une belle mise en forme.
Trump: The Ignoramus Who Thinks He’s a Genius
Trump considers himself a genius, but his approach relies on methods already employed by his predecessors. What sets him apart is not innovation, but a lack of scruples in their application. This attitude does not reflect genius, but rather an ignorance of the harmful consequences he inflicts on the American economy.
Concentration of Benefits
The tariffs imposed by Donald Trump, notably during his presidency (2017-2021), should be seen as a political tool for concentrating benefits and diffusing costs for several reasons. As explained in your text, Trump’s tariffs primarily served specific interests (certain industries and lobbying groups) while distributing the costs across all American consumers and businesses. In this sense, they exemplify a policy where the benefits are concentrated among a few well-identified actors, while the costs are widely dispersed across the population—a typical phenomenon of economically motivated electoral decisions.
Ignorance
Trump capitalizes on the rational ignorance of American voters because he knows that many do not take the time to deeply analyze public policies or fact-check information. He prefers to play on emotions and perceptions rather than economic facts. This is a rational choice within an electoral logic, even if it harms the country’s overall economy.
Why Is This Politically Rational?
Simple and Effective Messaging: “America First,” “We protect our jobs,” “Foreigners are stealing our wealth.” These are striking slogans that are easy for the electorate to understand.
Mobilization of the Electoral Base: Trump consolidated his support among workers in industrial states (Pennsylvania, Michigan, Ohio, Wisconsin).
Scapegoating: The tariffs allow for blaming external enemies (China, Mexico, EU) and explaining economic difficulties as the fault of “others,” rather than structural problems within the United States.
Short-Term Effects: In the short term, certain industries seem to benefit from the tariffs, which can be used as proof of success, even if the effect diminishes in the long term.
When Genius and Ignorance Are in Close Proximity
Unlike voters, whose ignorance is a rational choice, Trump embodies true ignorance, unaware that he is merely recycling outdated policies. By betting on short-term measures suited to a four-year term and unscrupulously applying worn-out recipes, he has managed to elevate himself to the rank of an American hero. But I would wager that he is not even aware of his actions.
God bless America!
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 3 2025 at 4:23pm
Pierre: I broadly agree. Trump is the reincarnation of 17th-century Jean-Baptiste Colbert, without the intelligence. “Ignoramus” is the right term. (And I did notice recently that ChatGPT has much improved over the past couple of years, notably in translation. You have no more excuse for not regularly participating in EconLog !)
Roger McKinney
Mar 1 2025 at 12:36pm
Great points! Unfortunately, these tariffs are insanely popular. My son told me his boss, a CPA, is so excited that Trump will make the US much richer through tariffs. We’ve a long way to go to educate people.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 1 2025 at 1:14pm
Thanks, Roger. And you are alas right. But with some optimism, the tariffs scheduled for next week could help people understand. The dark side is that to muddle the lesson, Trump would do something else–like, say, starting a war with Mexico! (And Vance would soon say that the war with Mexico and recession were caused by Mexicans eating American pets.)
Jon Murphy
Mar 1 2025 at 1:40pm
I don’t think that’s the case. I read a poll just this morning that found only about a third of people supported tariffs. Broken down by country, about 40% supported tariffs on China, but it plummeted to low double digits for other countries. I’ll find it for you.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 1 2025 at 1:51pm
Jon: That’s a good point. It seems quite clear that a (vast) majority of Americans are not autarkic and xenophobic like the duo Trump-Vance. Most Americans who run their own businesses or are high managers (perhaps even middle managers) have a good intuition of the consequences of tariffs.
Mactoul
Mar 1 2025 at 8:34pm
Vance could be a lot of things but, with a son named Vivek, xenophobic is not one of these.
Jon Murphy
Mar 1 2025 at 8:57pm
Why not? You said above that the whole purpose of the state is to be xenophobic.
Thomas L Hutcheson
Mar 2 2025 at 2:38pm
Strom Thurmond’s son? 🙂
I’d say the cat eating speech outweighs making an exception for family.
But who cares what his motivation for Making American Weaker Again” are?
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 3 2025 at 11:03am
Thomas: I agree. And Musk also eats pets. https://www.nytimes.com/2025/02/18/us/politics/steve-bannon-elon-musk-feud.html
Student of Liberty
Mar 2 2025 at 9:01am
and then
Something does not add up here. Could it be that 75% applies to the total imports of aluminum rather that total consumption?
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 3 2025 at 4:08pm
“Anonymous” Student: Thanks for this, but I can’t find where my mistake would be. If we look at the USGS overview of aluminum, we can verify that the total production in the US (4,270 million tons estimated for 2024) is 44% of the supply (production + imports) of 9,730 million tons), which roughly corresponds to my “roughly 40%.”
As for the 75%, this is the number given by the WSJ story that I cite: “Canada is now the largest supplier of primary aluminum to the U.S., accounting for 75% of the total primary aluminum consumed by the U.S., according to the Aluminum Association.” I get close to that in the USGS survey data for 2014, that is, 71% = 3058 (56% of 5,460) divided by 4,000.
These aluminum data are very confusing. My confusion (if I did make a mistake) may be because there are two sorts of aluminum production, primary and from scrap, and imported scrap is not included in trade data. Let me/us know if you find a solution.
Jose Pablo
Mar 3 2025 at 7:51pm
My difficulty with the argument of those who, like some Trump voters, support tariffs, is understanding where they stop being beneficial.
If tariffs are good for the U.S., they should also be good for Alabama, which could impose its own tariffs to boost local industries like aluminum smelting. By that logic, Jefferson County could do the same against the rest of the state, and Birmingham might follow suit.
Ultimately, why not impose tariffs at home? My family could start producing its own food, clothing, and even a car.
We’d all be very busy—I just doubt we’d be better off.
We could even live off the money raised through my “home tariffs” … but, wait ….
Comments are closed.