Does Protectionism Protect?

In a National Review article documenting the failure of steel and aluminum tariffs to accomplish their stated goals, my friend and GMU classmate Dominic Pino writes:

The case for protectionism can be framed as the government making you a little poorer for your own good.  The problem is that the ‘making you a little poorer’ part usually happens, and the ‘for your own good’ part usually does not.

I, too, have documented the failure of the protectionist tariffs started under the Trump Administration and perpetuated under the Biden Administration in accomplishing their stated goals.  Jobs have not been created, new firms have not come about, production has not expanded.  Americans are paying significantly more for various goods and services, but are not getting the supposed benefits from protectionism.  

And let us consider an older piece of protectionist legislation: the Jones Act.  Despite being in continuous operation for over a century, the Jones Act has utterly failed to protect and promote American shipbuilding capacity.  Indeed, shipbuilding capacity is lower now in 2024 than when the Act was passed in 1920.  Even Adam Smith argues that national defense is a justification for tariffs (“As defence, however, is of much more importance than opulence, the act of nation is, perhaps, the wisest of gall the commercial regulations of England”).  But why is it that opulence is sacrificed but defense not generated?

Let us consider the typical argument for protectionism from an economic point of view: the higher prices from the tariff should induce domestic suppliers to produce more even while domestic consumers consume less.  The decline in consumption comes from fewer imports and not domestic production.  So far, so good.  Some “opulence” is sacrificed through higher prices, but at least producers can produce and sell more!

But this argument is from a very limited perspective.  The supply and demand model is powerful, but it is also static.  It rests on a ceteris paribus (“all else held equal”) assumption, but the ceteris is not paribus for long.  As things change, the protection afforded by tariffs weakens.  Indeed, the protection weakens because of the tariffs.  Tariffs sow the seeds of their own destruction.

In economics, we all know the Law of Demand: there is an inverse relationship between quantity demanded and price.  But there is another Law of Demand, sometimes referred to as the 2nd Law of Demand: the longer a price remains relatively high, the more sensitive consumers become to a change in price, and the more they search out or develop substitutes.  Eventually, it is possible that a sufficient number of substitutes come about that the demand curve for the product starts to fall as fewer individuals participate in the market.  Since protectionist tariffs intentionally raise prices, the good under protection becomes subject to this 2nd Law of Demand and consumers can eventually start shifting away, meaning that the tariff itself leads to the industry being smaller than it otherwise would.

We have seen this outcome with the Jones Act.  With marine shipping between American ports relatively expensive, both because of the Jones Act’s requirements and the dwindling number of Act-compliant ships, other forms of transportation have arisen.  In particular, over-land shipping (trucking, rail, pipelines, etc.) and air have become more popular.  In some cases, states have turned to international trade because importing is cheaper than paying domestic shipping rates.  For example, Massachusetts imports much of its oil and natural gas from countries like Russia because the Jones Act makes it prohibitively expensive to ship energy from American ports along the Gulf of Mexico.  As these new substitutions take on a larger and larger role, the demand for Jones Act compliant ships has fallen.  The Jones Act seems to have weakened national defense and shipbuilding capabilities, rather than protect it.  

To what extent the 2nd Law of Demand plays empirically, I do not know.  There may be more important factors at play.  It’s an empirical question.  But what is an empirical fact: protectionism fails in its stated goals.

 


Jon Murphy is an assistant professor of economics at Nicholls State University.

READER COMMENTS

Bill
Mar 24 2024 at 12:02pm

Well done, Jon.

Jon Murphy
Mar 24 2024 at 12:10pm

Thank you!

steve
Mar 24 2024 at 9:07pm

Austin Vernon has a pretty extensive critique on why we have trouble building enough ships for the Navy. It’s partly due to govt interference and partly due to how we build ships. Of note, protectionism started well before the Jones Act. Also, we have about 100,000 shipyard workers about 30% more than Japan which produces abut 20x our tonnage.

https://austinvernon.site/blog/navyshipbuilding.html

Steve

Warren Platts
Mar 26 2024 at 12:51am

 For example, Massachusetts imports much of its oil and natural gas from countries like Russia because the Jones Act makes it prohibitively expensive to ship energy from American ports along the Gulf of Mexico.

This is a myth that keeps getting repeated by people that ought to know better, like Casey Mulligan. What happened was in 2018, there were two shipments of LNG that were sent to the United Kingdom. A political uproar ensued, and the solution decided upon was to re-export an equivalent amount of natural gas to the United States. So it’s highly unlikely that the actual methane molecules imported into Boston’s harbor even originated from Russian gas wells. Those were the only two LNG shipments ever received from the UK. The USA has never received a direct shipment of Russian LNG. Such LNG that is imported by New England comes mostly from Trinidad, a tiny island country off the coast of Venezuala. Anyways, poor Massachusetts could have all the natural gas in the world if they would just build a freakin’ pipeline, but the wacko enviros that run that place make it impossible to get the required permits. So if we’re going to point fingers, at least point them in the right direction: the Jones Act isn’t the cause of New England energy scarcity.

Jon Murphy
Mar 26 2024 at 1:14am

You’re quite right that New England in general could reduce their dependency on imported natural gas and oil if they allowed a pipeline to be built. That’s further evidence of the inability of the Jones Act to protect American shipbuilding and how it unintentionally makes Americans worse off.

Warren Platts
Mar 26 2024 at 6:53pm

Welp. Look at what just happened: a thousand foot, non-Jones Act, foreign container ship manned by 8 crew members most of whom don’t even make $7.25 an hour just destroyed the Francis Scott Key bridge in Baltimore. At least six people are dead, and the entire harbor is closed down for commerce for who knows how long. This is exactly why we don’t want foreign operators running barges down the Mississippi River…

Warren Platts
Apr 1 2024 at 3:08pm

Hmm… This is interesting. It turns out that the Trump washing machine tariffs only temporarily raised prices (due to greed inflation most likely for the most part imho) and then declined to pre-tariff price levels due to increased competition among domestic producers that now includes LG & Samsung.

The CPI for laundry equipment peaked at 102 in June 2018. By December 2019, it was down to 89.3, slightly below the pre-tariff level of 90.7 in January 2018. So the Flaaen, Hortacsu, Tintelnot article was effectively obsolete eight months after its April 2019 publication.

This implies that virtually all of the subsequent tariff revenue from December 2019 to 2023 (when the washing machine tariffs expired) represented terms-of-trade gains (i.e., when the tax burden of the tariff fell on foreign producers rather than home consumers), and likely resulted in a net gain to net welfare for the USA. Apparently, the Big Country theory of tariffs actually works!

Comments are closed.

RECENT POST

Here are some highlights of my weekly reading. How FDR Made Republican Isolationists Look Silly with a Simple Rhyme by Charles Sykes, Politico, March 20, 2024. Excerpt: In the speech, Roosevelt deployed the full force of his rhetorical talents against three leading Republican isolationist leaders: Mass. Rep. Jo...

Read More

Last year, the consensus view of economists called for a recession in 2023.  At the time, I said this sort of prediction is foolish, as the science of economics has no method for predicting turning points in the business cycle.  It was akin to astronomers trying to emulate astrologers, and made the profession look fo...

Read More

In a National Review article documenting the failure of steel and aluminum tariffs to accomplish their stated goals, my friend and GMU classmate Dominic Pino writes: The case for protectionism can be framed as the government making you a little poorer for your own good.  The problem is that the ‘making you a litt...

Read More