Friedrich Hayek argued that only action can be just or unjust. So, when the famous Austrian playwright and novelist Ödön von Horváth was promenading on the Champs-Élysées during a thunderstorm and was hit—and ultimately killed—by a bough of some tree, we cannot speak of injustice. The tree did not intend to kill him; it just happened.
But Hayek’s view that justice only meaningfully applies to actions has further (and perhaps more important) implications. It also implies that the income and wealth patterns in a pure market economy are neither just nor unjust. While it certainly can be just or unjust how two people in the market economy interact, the specific order resulting from the interaction of millions of people is neither just nor unjust. As nobody plans the overall order (there is no action, no guiding will behind it), it is beyond justice.
Today’s economies are mixed systems. In these systems, there is generally a free market process. Therefore, generally, the specific order that emerges is beyond justice. However, governments do intervene, that is, they, relying on coercion, interfere with people’s free actions. While perhaps not all, some interventions are intended to shape the income and wealth patterns in society. And to the degree that these interventions then impact the overall pattern of wealth in society, justice becomes applicable: how the government shapes these patterns can be just or unjust. For instance, governments tax inheritances with the purpose of preventing rising inequality, or they bail out ailing banks (as occurred after the 2008 crisis).
You need not find this problematic per se. Perhaps there are good reasons for the interventions. However, even if generally fine, it is only unproblematic if all government interventions are actually just.
As soon as some government interventions are unjust, however, a delicate situation emerges, because then we have an income and wealth pattern that is partly the result of unjust actions and that can thus be partly called just or unjust. To make this clear, if in a pure market economy you are poor or lose your job, you are just like Ödön von Horváth. You may be angry with your fate, but you haven’t been treated unjustly. But if you are poor or lose your job in a mixed economy, this may be (partly) the result of governmental action, that is, government’s unjust coercion-based actions. But then you may have justified claims to governmental action in order to retribute the prior injustice. And perhaps more. In Sanford Ikeda’s words, “once the redistributive intervention takes place, those who lose as a result now have a legitimate and identifiable target, i.e., the central authority and its supporters, to blame.”
If this reasoning is correct, our evaluation of numerous actions of citizens within the mixed economy becomes very difficult, if not impossible. It’s a mess! For instance, if the bakery around the corner evades taxes, is this unjust? (That it is illegal is surely the case, but legality is not morality.) Once you acknowledge that the government has erected an insidiously complex regulatory regime that favours big companies who, with their lawyers and consultants, are better able to manoeuvre the mixed economy, it is no longer possible to pronounce a clear verdict. But also when we examine the actions of big players such as Apple it soon becomes evident that it is really difficult to find a good vantage point from whence to judge their actions, including attempts to capture regulation. For they may also be victims of unjust government intervention—a point in case is probably the EU Commission’s decision to punish Apple for allegedly exploiting its power in the music streaming business.
In the imperfect mixed economy, then, people and companies who evade taxes, who violate the law, who implement schemes to circumvent government interventions, may even have the moral high ground. They may be justified to do illegal stuff. And they may be justified to capture regulation or even fight for new regulation that favours their industry. I am not saying that they are justified. These are moral questions and these, if they have definite answers at all, surely require detailed and intricate analysis of each specific case.
But what is evident is that in an interventionist society, things really get messy and murky. It is not clear that those who do stuff that would definitely be reprehensible in the pure market economy, act reprehensibly in the mixed economy.
Max Molden is a PhD student at the University of Hamburg. He has worked with European Students for Liberty and Prometheus – Das Freiheitsinstitut. He regularly publishes at Der Freydenker.
READER COMMENTS
Roger McKinney
Aug 27 2024 at 4:08pm
Excellent points! Theologians kicked around the just price problem for 1500vl years, then concluded that the closest approximation to a just price price is in a free market. That’s why free markets were Protestant dogma for 400 years.
Monte
Aug 28 2024 at 1:15am
Specific, or spontaneous, order may produce mostly efficient outcomes, but Hayek acknowledged that injustices and inefficiencies still result, requiring some level of government intervention to correct. Markets, like people, are still subject to laws and regulations that govern their actions. The absence of will is just a mitigating factor for determining remediation.
Monte
Aug 28 2024 at 3:37pm
This is a bit of a kludge, but consider the following proposition:
If the individual values of justice and fairness are expressly written into the rules and norms that govern a market system, it operates in alignment with those values and, in the aggregate, reflects the collective will of each participant. This legal and regulatory framework ensures that the market upholds these values. The premise is then altered such that the market is not beyond justice, but rather operates within the boundaries of what is considered just and fair according to the collective values of the society.
Max Molden
Aug 29 2024 at 1:20pm
Re your first point: Firstly, there is not “the” Hayek. Beware that the man changed his views, particularly on government intervention. See his later introduction to the Road to Serfdom, in which he speaks of “interventionist superstitions” which he back then had not shaken off. Secondly, while Hayek would always have agreed that markets aren’t perfect, I am not so sure regarding their injustice; he may have allowed for a minimum income, but that doesn’t mean he did it on grounds of justice. But can you point me to some passage? Note also that to acknowledge justice and efficiency problems in markets does not imply that government interventions will help.
Re your second point: I like this a lot! And this is what Hayek took the early Rawls to be saying, as he remarks in LLL at some place. Also, are you familiar with the work of the ordoliberals? I only found German texts, but consider my translation of a key sentence: “Under competitive conditions, the institutional framework becomes the systematic place of morality.” Ingo Pies
Monte
Aug 29 2024 at 7:14pm
Thanks for the response, Max. You’re right, of course, to point out Hayek’s evolution of thought re: intervention, where early on he was adamantly opposed to any form of it, arguing that even the best of intentions could lead to loss of freedom and economic inefficiency (his overriding concern).
Only in terms of social justice and the role of government in mitigating market failures: “A just society can only be one where the rules of the game are fair and apply to everyone, and in which the government provides some minimal level of social security.” (The Constitution of Liberty)
Agreed, and (vis-a-vis Hayek) they often make things worse. Nevertheless, he accepted that interventions could be justified provided they did not impede market efficiency or the rule of law.
I’d never heard of “ordoliberals” or Ingo Pies, but having googled them reminds me of the fact that there is nothing new under the sun. There’s nothing novel in the crude proposition I put together that the ordoliberals and Ingo Pies didn’t already conceive of and write about in more eloquent terms than I could hope to. Thanks for the pointer!
Mactoul
Aug 28 2024 at 3:39am
But this raises the question of definition –what exactly is a pure market economy?
Max Molden
Aug 29 2024 at 1:27pm
I don’t think we’ll ever know. But from what I can tell, absolutely precise definitions will never be within reach. So, private property of the means of production, opposite to socialism and its planned economy, is a good rule of thumb. Even though it won’t offer you precise answers in a world in which we don’t know how to create and enforce all property rights perfectly. But I think that more important is our ability to clearly distinguish the three different systems from each other. It suffices to have clear examples to make a meaningful distinction between the economic systems with which we can work.
Regarding your second point, this is a fine argument, but note that my thesis was actually different: I wrote: “While perhaps not all, some interventions are intended to shape the income and wealth patterns in society. And to the degree that these interventions then impact the overall pattern of wealth in society, justice becomes applicable.” So, decisive are those government interventions with which individual actors intend to shape the patterns. I also believe that from a moral perspective the coerciveness of governmental action sets is strictly apart from citizens’ actions.
Mactoul
Aug 28 2024 at 10:34pm
Where is methodological individualism when we need it?
There is nothing called a government action– there are all actions executed by individuals.
So, if a pure market economy produces results that are beyond good and evil, because these acts were individual acts, so does the results in mixed economies and indeed in socialist economies as well.
Comments are closed.