
Considering sunk costs in one’s decisions is a cognitive limitation that behavioral economists may underestimate. If you, dear voter, have already lost $100,000 in a project that you are sure will continue to bring you net losses, you will just lose more money by putting more into it. Your previous cost is sunk and won’t be reimbursed to you just because you lose more money. As the dictum goes, don’t throw good money after bad money!
The sunk-cost fallacy is at work in political partisanship too. Suppose you have “invested,” if only emotionally, in politician X. You have followed him for years, applauding his good deeds and forgiving his bad ones: “he just said that to be elected,” “he did not have a choice,” “consider how politician W would be worse,” etc. Perhaps you even consciously swallowed the lies he wanted you to believe as a badge of loyalty. You were sometimes disappointed, perhaps betrayed, but you had faith that it would get better. It doesn’t get better but you continue to follow. You are a victim of the sunk-cost fallacy if you consider your past emotional investment as a reason for continuing to invest faith, hope, and emotions into X.
You may feel that there is an intellectual or moral reputation reason for doing so. Admitting that you were wrong or have been duped may indeed involve a reputational cost. But waiting longer may impose a still larger reputational cost on you. At any rate, your current decision should not take into account your emotional (or intellectual or moral) sunk costs.
The only reason, it seems, for which a (dismal) economist friend could give you for continuing to follow your politician hero revolves around specific human capital. You may have wasted much of your reputational capital (admittedly a sunk cost) and, in its place, accumulated very specific human capital—the ability to lie or blur the truth, for example—that has little value in honest life pursuits. I am not this dismal economist, but Merry Christmas anyway!
READER COMMENTS
John P. Palmer
Dec 24 2020 at 8:42am
Excellent. I often ask myself and my friends, “What would it take to change your mind?”
Applies also to being a die-hard sports team fan. Or to staying in a relationship too long.
Kenny Rogers: you got to know when to hold ‘em and know when to fold ‘em.
David Q
Dec 24 2020 at 10:40am
I’m very curious if this post flips anyone from favoring Politician X to no longer favoring Politician X.
Let us know!
David Q
Pierre Lemieux
Dec 24 2020 at 11:22am
@David Q: I am all years. Let me know what you hear too!
Howard Roberts
Dec 24 2020 at 1:00pm
Yes, our President’s despicable behaviour post-election has made me deeply regret any support I had for him. Excusing the vulgarity and lies for the sake of three supreme court apointees was foolish and I certainly regret it. Unfortunate it took this long to recognize the truth.
Craig
Dec 28 2020 at 12:08pm
Personally I don’t judge Trump by his actions, but rather what I’m able to do. TJCA is a big deal. I’m sorry but I came from high tax blue state like NJ where taxes all in were 56%.
I moved to FL and of course TJCA.
If Republicans hold Senate, presumably TJCA will stand. Nevertheless, support for Trump is hardly a sunk cost. I voted. My investment is minimal, but the dividends are very real, very large and if they hold the Senate will continue.
One side wants to pack courts and make a moral claim to more than half my income. Yes, there are #NeverTrumpers but there ARE #NEVERDEMOCRATS
I have never regretted opposing the Democratic Party.
Jose Pablo
Dec 29 2020 at 8:46am
This is a living proof that Ricardian equivalence is a pure theoretical exercise. TJCA did not “reduce” taxes, only postpone them. You can only “properly” reduce taxes by reducing expending.
Ricardo and Barrow would “advice” you (well they say you will do it by yourself) saving your “tax savings” and passing them to your kids and grandkids to pay for the inevitable future tax increases that sure should follow the deficit (and new debt) cause by the TJCA.
And they are regarded as very serious economists … how crazy ah!!
Craig
Dec 29 2020 at 10:02am
I do agree that spending is taxation of course in a broad sense, but the physical taxes still sets the tone. I foresaw this result going back to Trump’s win in 2016 even. Here’s the bottom line, short of a secession (and that is currently a low probability result right now), the culture of confiscation is deep seated. Its an absolute cancer. You have no hope of getting rid of it.
Go where you are treated best…..See my new Svengali Andrew Henderson on the Nomad Capitalist. Also of note for at least a few would be Mitko Karshavski on thatremotelife
Jose Pablo
Dec 29 2020 at 11:37am
Congratulations on voting with your feet.
It is always a pleasure to see governments struggling to keep people inside the “Paradises on Earth” that, they claim, their central planning has created.
Jose Pablo
Dec 29 2020 at 12:11pm
By the way …
https://www.econlib.org/connect-the-dots/
Mark Brady
Dec 25 2020 at 6:30pm
Here is a heretical thought. Most cases of “sunk costs” that my fellow economists cite are not really sunk, and therefore do not illustrate the fallacy of sunk costs.
And here’s another heretical thought. Do my fellow economists perhaps unwittingly provide examples of the fallacy of sunk costs when sometimes they write on this topic?
Jon Murphy
Dec 26 2020 at 10:48am
I’m not really sure how heretical a thought that is. Our journals are filled with articles that discuss how this or that example is not really an example of a particular concept. For example, see Coase’s famous paper “The Lighthouse in Economics.” Or the earlier quote from Stiglitz discussing how education is not a public good. Indeed, I argue that pretty much all econ textbooks get externalities wrong.
Jose Pablo
Dec 29 2020 at 8:55am
I argue that pretty much always the “externalities” are got wrong or lead to the wrong conclusion …
… namely “so government should intervene” as if government interventions were magically free of “externalities” (a believe that implicitly and wrongly supports this conclusion).
Warren Platts
Dec 26 2020 at 9:53am
An excellent takedown of Biden supporters, Pierre!
Craig
Dec 28 2020 at 12:23pm
Left is like playing with friends as a kid who was only ok if he got the cookie. If they don’t get the cookie they will burn down Best Buy.
Bush/Romney/McCain are now all rehabilitated but were subject to a fair amount of vitriol when they stood opposite the left. Trump is no different but he is particularly easy to dislike.
Supreme Court HRC threw the equivalent of a pick 6 and so now they want to pack the court. There were consequences to losing but they don’t want to accept them. Left doesn’t except limitations on their agenda. They are expert incrementalists and YES they are slow boiling the lobster.
Yves Guerard
Dec 27 2020 at 12:19pm
Unfortunately most people don’t like to be wrong and try to avoid it encurring not only sunk costs but continuing ones until intellectual bankruptcy! A les polite dictum is “An idiot is born every day” . No cheers!
Weir
Dec 27 2020 at 5:25pm
A great example is the columnist in the New York Times who told us that his hero “is the personification of decency, and if he wins he’ll do his best to restore our standards of behavior.”
Once you’ve put those words down in print you’re really committing yourself to blocking out everything that suggests your hero isn’t “the personification of decency.”
Mark Z
Dec 27 2020 at 11:35pm
Suppose you’re a Bayesian, and you don’t know much about a topic and are listening to two people, A and B, argue about it. They previously argued about a different topic, on which B ultimately publicly admitted he was wrong and A was right. On the current topic, who is more likely to be right? A probably, right? The consensus is that A is 1 for 1 and B is 0 for 1. Admitting you’re wrong about something can thus harm your credibility before future audiences. With politics, you’re also forfeiting moral credibility as well, since you’re also likely admitting (in the minds of your audience) that you are a bad person. It may thus be strategic – if your wrongness is not self-evident to everyone else – to refuse to admit being wrong even if you personally know you’re wrong.
Jon Murphy
Dec 28 2020 at 7:04am
I don’t follow your reasoning.
Jon Murphy
Dec 28 2020 at 8:24am
Here’s where you lose me:
I don’t see why, from a Bayesian perspective, one admitting he was wrong about something inherently means losing credibility.
A true Bayesian reasoner adjusts his opinion all the time based on new evidence. Depending on the strength of his prior, new evidence could cause him to switch opinions and admit previously held ones were incorrect.
So, if A and B are arguing, A presents sufficiently strong evidence that B is incorrect, and B acknowledges and admits defeat, the impartial Bayesian (call him S for Spectator) would update his priors about B. S would update his priors to say that B learns from the evidence and adjusts as needed. In future arguments, S may be more positively inclined to B than previously given the new information S has about B.
Conversely, if B refused to change his mind even given strong/overwhelming evidence, S may adjust his priors in a negative manner and become less inclined to B in future arguments.
Mark Z
Dec 28 2020 at 3:12pm
I’m assuming that S doesn’t have enough knowledge to ascertain who is right independently. B’s willingness to change lends less to his credibility than A being right in the first place. I agree that B is more credible in future ’rounds’ than he would have been if he’d refuse to change his view, then was externally proven wrong beyond doubt.
Both being wrong and being intransigent about admitting you’re wrong reflect poorly on one’s judgment. If, at the end of the debate, both participants still disagree, and S is only, say, 60% sure that A is right, then there’s a 60% chance B is not only wrong but intransigent. But if B relents and admits he is wrong, S is now 100% sure that B was wrong (I’m assuming one side conceding means this). I don’t think it can be trivially assumed that B gains more credibility by proving he’s not intransigent than he loses by proving that he was wrong. It depends quite a bit on how likely the question is to be settled externally to a certainty, in the eyes of the spectator, at some point in the future.
Jon Murphy
Dec 28 2020 at 3:53pm
Sure, but I don’t think it can be assumed that he loses credibility, either.
I am assuming that S watches the whole discussion (if he doesn’t and just sees B conceding, then a good Bayesian would conclude he doesn’t have information to sway his priors). The context of the conversation matters.
Jose Pablo
Dec 29 2020 at 9:11am
The whole reasoning assumes that a political argument (or a politician) can be proved right or wrong.
This is just an “overstatement”, as Tetlock shows in “Expert Political Judgement”. Political issues are just too complex for people to understand let alone to make accurate predictions about them. And, in any circumstance, “the ingenuity and determination that political elites display in rendering their positions impregnable to evidence” will triumph.
So, if you are listening to two people discussing about politics or politicians just assume (no matter how Bayesian you are) that both are wrong … just for different reasons
Jon Murphy
Dec 29 2020 at 1:19pm
Not necessarily. Mark Z’s argument can be applied to anything
Jose Pablo
Dec 29 2020 at 3:10pm
Yes, you are right.
I think my solution, assuming both wrong, applies when A and B are discussing politics and/or economics (at least), pretty much for the same reasons.
Jose Pablo
Dec 29 2020 at 6:54pm
Definitely a side thought, but, regarding the sunk cost concept: does it apply to marriage?
Just wondering … should you take into account your emotional (and financial) costs/investments for the last 15-30 years when deciding who to spend the next 30-15 years with? or is the question do I want to spend one more day with this man/woman and what are the future cash-flow consequences the only relevant ones?
Just putting the theory to the test …
Comments are closed.