The Coolidge Curve

When the United States entered World War One in 1917, tax rates were increased to pay for it and remained high after the war. The federal income tax was enacted in 1913 with a starting rate of 1.0% on income under $20,000 ($621,000 in 2023 dollars) – at a time when the average income was about $600 ($18,600) – and a top rate of 7.0% on income over $500,000 ($15.5 million), and 358,000 returns were filed.

At the time of President Warren G. Harding’s sudden death and succession by Calvin Coolidge in August 1923, the starting rate was 4.0% on income under $4,000, the top rate was 58.0% on income over $200,000, and 7.7 million returns were filed.

 

Nevertheless, spending ran significantly ahead of revenues. As a result, federal government debt leapt from $1.2 billion in 1914 to $25 billion in 1919; indeed, by 1919 the interest on the debt was as large as the debt itself had been in 1914.

Part of the problem was that higher rates did not necessarily yield higher revenues. As Thomas Sowell notes:

…the number of people reporting taxable incomes of more than $300,000…declined from well over a thousand in 1916 to fewer than three hundred in 1921 [and] The total amount of taxable income earned by people making over $300,000 declined by more than four-fifths…there was no reason to believe that the wealthy were suddenly suffering drastic reductions in their own incomes, but considerable reason to believe that they were receiving tax-exempt incomes that did not have to be reported under existing laws at that time.

The Treasury Department estimated that investment in tax exempt securities like municipal bonds had nearly tripled in a decade.

Harding blasted a federal “financial orgy” but struggled to restrain it. Coolidge set about the task with relish. With his budget director, Herbert Lord, he set targets for spending cuts, and he developed tax cuts with Treasury secretary Andrew Mellon. He announced his tax reforms in December; tax exempt securities would lose their special status and tax rates would be cut. Coolidge, who had a moral aversion to high taxes, echoed Mellon’s argument that lower rates “will not greatly reduce the revenue from that source, and may in the future actually increase it” by stimulating economic growth.

Coolidge and Mellon secured a compromise tax cut in 1924, but it wasn’t until Coolidge won a mandate of his own with victory in that year’s presidential election that their tax bill passed. As they pushed the bill through Congress, Amity Shlaes writes:

In desperation, the opponents of the legislation began to quantify the share of the tax break that the wealthy would claim. This, they were discovering, was an easy way to frame an opponent. General, across-the-board cuts of any progressive structure always favored the rich, since they had been paying more under the progressivity to begin with. Senator George Norris pointed out, “Mr. Mellon himself gets a larger personal reduction than the aggregate of practically all the taxpayers in the state of Nebraska.” So he did. But Mellon paid more tax than the citizens of the state as well.

Coolidge was successful and by 1925 the starting rate of federal income tax was 1.5% on income under $4,000, the top rate was 25.0% on income over $100,000, and 4.2 million returns were filed.

And, as rates fell, revenues rose, especially from the rich. Cutting income tax rates and ending the tax exemption of securities like municipal bonds caused people to move their capital from non-taxable but economically unproductive investments into taxable – at lower rates – but economically productive investments which generated higher rates of economic growth, widespread prosperity, and higher tax revenues.

The number of people reporting incomes of over a million dollars increased from 21 in 1921 to 207 by 1925. Sowell writes that:

In 1921, when the tax rate on people making over $100,000 a year was 73 percent, the federal government collected a little over $700 million in income taxes, of which 30 percent was paid by those making over $100,000. By 1929, after a series of tax rate reductions had cut the tax rate to 24 percent on those making over $100,000, the federal government collected more than a billion dollars in income taxes, of which 65 percent was collected from those making over $100,000.

It isn’t true that tax cuts will always pay for themselves as Coolidge’s did, but neither is it true that cutting taxes will always reduce revenues. This was the central – correct – insight encapsulated in the famous ‘Laffer Curve’ in the 1970s. By then, however, it was at least 50 years old and might just have well been called the ‘Coolidge Curve.’

 


READER COMMENTS

Mark Brady
Aug 10 2023 at 3:55pm

Laffer’s insight is not original to Laffer, and Laffer did not claim that it was.

“Nor should the argument seem strange that taxation may be so high as to defeat its object, and that, given sufficient time to gather the fruits, a reduction of taxation will run a better chance, than an increase, of balancing the Budget. For to take the opposite view to-day is to resemble a manufacturer who, running at a loss, decides to raise his price, and when his declining sales increase the loss, wrapping himself in the rectitude of plain arithmetic, decides that prudence requires him to raise the price still more;—and who, when at last his account is balanced with nought on both sides, is still found righteously declaring that it would have been the act of a gambler to reduce the price when you were already making a loss.”

—John Maynard Keynes, The Means to Prosperity (London: Macmillan & Co., 1933), Chapter I, The Nature of the Problem, p. 7.  (This pamphlet is an enlarged version of four articles printed in The Times in March 1933.)

“If a tax is gradually increased from zero up to the point where it becomes prohibitive, its yield is at first nil, then increases by small stages until it reaches a maximum, after which it gradually declines until it becomes zero again. It follows that when the state requires to raise a given sum by means of taxation, there are always two rates of tax which will fulfil the requirement, one above and one below that which would yield the maximum.”

—Arsène-Jules-Emile Juvenal Dupuit (1804-66), a French engineer and economic theorist (pioneering cost-benefit analysis), in “De la mesure de l’utilité des travaux publics,” Annales des ponts et chaussées, Second series, 8 (1844), p. 104.  Translated by R.H. Barback as “On the measurement of the utility of public works,” International Economic Papers, 2 (1952): 83–110.

So, as you can see, Jules Dupuit (1804-66) and J. M. Keynes (1883-1946) anticipated the insight popularly associated with Arthur Betz Laffer (1940-).

Richard W Fulmer
Aug 10 2023 at 4:51pm

“Boni pastoris est tondere pecus non deglubere” (A good shepherd shears his sheep, he does not flay them.)
Tiberius Caesar Augustus (42 BC – 37 AD, Roman emperor warning his regional commanders to avoid excessive taxation).

“At the beginning of a dynasty, taxation yields a large revenue from small assessments. At the end of the dynasty, taxation yields a small revenue from large assessments.”
Ibn Khaldun (1332-1406, Arab sociologist, philosopher, and historian)

Andrew_FL
Aug 10 2023 at 8:27pm

Correct, in fact Laffer himself likes to say you can find the seed of the idea in the writings of Ibn Khaldun

Kurt Schuler
Aug 11 2023 at 11:32am

See Bruce Bartlett’s history of how a number of people have expressed the idea of the Laffer Curve over the centuries:

https://equitablegrowth.org/bruce-bartletts-complete-history-laffer-curve-ibn-khaldun-ronald-reagan/

Thomas L Hutcheson
Aug 12 2023 at 5:21pm

I’d be more interested in understanding the failure to eliminate the corporate income tax when the personal tax was instituted.  That, like the delay in going off gold, not taxing employees for purchases of health insurance  seems to be one of those “sliding doors” moments.

Comments are closed.

RECENT POST

My favorite economist is Tyler Cowen. But this isn't because he has a great track record at predicting things---none of the greats do. Unfortunately, our society places way too much weight on prediction. Even worse, we don't know how to evaluate whether people have done a good job at predicting.  Bubbles are a great e...

Read More

  And, challenges remain in ensuring equal pay for equal work. In 2022, among all salary workers in the White House, a woman made just 80 cents every dollar paid to a man. This is from a blog post written by an economist with President Biden's Council of Economic Advisers. It takes some courage to call out "...

Read More

When the United States entered World War One in 1917, tax rates were increased to pay for it and remained high after the war. The federal income tax was enacted in 1913 with a starting rate of 1.0% on income under $20,000 ($621,000 in 2023 dollars) - at a time when the average income was about $600 ($18,600) - and a to...

Read More