The Quantity Theory of Money in the Weimar Hyperinflation

In my two previous posts (here and here) I described how hyperinflation hit the Weimar Republic after the end of World War 1. On November 15, 1923, the German Papiermark hit an exchange rate of 2.5 trillion to $1. Two weeks earlier, $1 had bought 133 billion marks; at the start of the year 17,972 marks; on the currency’s introduction in 1914, 4.19. Germany’s currency died. What killed it?  

We can begin to answer that question with the equation of exchange, only of the few genuinely useful equations in economics:

MV=Py

This says that the money supply in an economy (M) multiplied by the number of times it is spent in a given period (velocity of circulation, V) equals the price level (P) multiplied by output (y); nominal spending (MV) equals nominal income (Py).  

Assuming that V and y are fixed, it follows that any increase in M must lead to an increase in P: inflation. But in Germany in 1921-1923, Theo Balderston writes, “prices did not rise in step with the money supply as the quantity theory implies.” Instead, he notes that:

..whereas the rate of growth of the monetary base was fairly steady from 1916 to mid-1922, the rate of price rise was anything but steady. In particular, the money supply continued to grow, albeit slowly, in 1920-21, while prices were falling.

The quantity theory of money – as restated by Milton Friedman – can account for this, however. It incorporates the ‘demand for money,’ or the demand to hold cash balances. Balderston explains that holding money balances:

…gives the holder benefits, chiefly in terms of the convenience of liquidity – the ability to spend without forethought. Thus, a stock of ready money is an asset. However, the convenience afforded by this asset must be balanced against the loss of income or pleasure due to holding one’s wealth in this form…because there is an opportunity cost to holding money, people will not hold unlimited amounts of it.

When those opportunity costs change, so does the demand for money. Besides the “‘opportunity cost’ of holding wealth as money balances in terms of the interest income foregone,” Balderston notes that:

There is also an ‘opportunity cost’ in holding wealth as money and not as goods if prices are expected to rise, and, finally, in domestic and not in foreign currency if the domestic currency is expected to depreciate. One can therefore hypothesise that, if domestic price inflation and/or nominal interest rates, and/or currency depreciation are expected to increase, the ‘opportunity cost’ of holding real money balances will be perceived to rise, and individuals and firms will economise on these balances.

They ‘economise’ by spending their balances: in other words, when the opportunity cost of holding money balances is perceived to rise, the demand for money falls, V increases, and p rises, even if M is kept constant. And, in reverse, when the opportunity cost of holding money balances is perceived to fall, the demand for money rises, V decreases, and p falls, even if M is kept constant. 

Data on the forward exchange rate of the mark from 1921 do show a stable, negative relationship between expected inflation and the real demand for money. What drove expectations? Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich, Balderston notes, “connected expectational changes to reparations crises.” Germany was wrangling with the Allies over the terms of the Versailles Treaty which had concluded World War One. In April 1921, the Allies presented their bill. Seen as unpayable by most Germans, they believed the government would resort to printing money to meet its liabilities. The opportunity cost of holdings marks was perceived to rise and Germans sought to ‘economize’ on their mark holdings by spending them. Further fiscal pressures arising from the Franco-Belgian occupation of the Rhur in January 1923 exacerbated this.    

But there is a limit to this. The demand for real money balances cannot fall below a certain level because the time between acquiring money and spending it cannot be compressed to zero. By late 1922, Frank D. Graham argued, marks were being spent as fast as possible. This was the period of people running to the shops as soon as they received their wages. 

Thus, Balderston argues, “in the long run, inflation cannot persist if the money supply does not expand.” “In this final period,” he writes, “inflation was probably driven by the money-supply process” outlined by Steven B. Webb, who argued that inflation expectations prompted people to dump government debt which the central bank bought with newly printed money to keep government borrowing costs down.  

Milton Friedman famously argued that:

Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon in the sense that it is and can be produced only by a more rapid increase in the quantity of money than in output.

That description fits the Weimar hyperinflation, even if the story is a little more nuanced than that famous formulation suggests.        

 


READER COMMENTS

vince
Nov 17 2023 at 3:35pm

 

Milton Friedman famously argued that:

Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon in the sense that it is and can be produced only by a more rapid increase in the quantity of money than in output.

What about an increase in velocity?  Or credit?

Monte
Nov 17 2023 at 3:52pm

At one point, rates exceeded 30,000%, causing prices to more than double every few days:

Menus in cafes could not be revised quickly enough. A student at Freiburg University ordered a cup of coffee at a cafe. The price on the menu was 5,000 Marks. He had two cups. When the bill came, it was for 14,000 Marks. “If you want to save money,” he was told, “and you want two cups of coffee, you should order them both at the same time.”

Many Germans resorted to burning paper money to stay warm in the winter, since it was less expensive to do that than purchase wood.

There are several forms of this equation: transactions, income, and cash balance.  Which would you use to describe the current situation in Argentina, where hyperinflation has apparently become a permanent part of the economy’s DNA?

Mike Sproul
Nov 17 2023 at 8:44pm

“the equation of exchange, only of the few genuinely useful equations in economics:

MV=Py

 

The equation of exchange is a tautology: “Money spent”=”Money received”. It is a genuinely useless equation.

Tom Sargent, in his paper entitled “The Ends of Four Big Inflations” concluded that the European hyperinflations of the 1920’s were better explained by the Backing Theory than by the Quantity Theory.

Monte
Nov 18 2023 at 2:12am

The equation of exchange is a tautology: “Money spent”=”Money received”. It is a genuinely useless equation.

No more a tautology than rt=d, the most used formula in physics and engineering.  But I’m unfamiliar with  “backing theory”.  Is this the same as the “real bills doctrine” Sargent and Wallace wrote about in their paper claiming that the one was more Pareto optimal than the other?  If so, it has been roundly criticized and rejected in a number of circles within the economics profession.

Murray Rothbard, in “Man, Economy, and State”, also presented a strong, but (IMHO) less than unequivocal, case for “expunging the equation of exchange from the economic literature.”

To suggest that the equation of exchange is useless in explaining the Weimar hyperinflation of the 1920s (or, for that matter, Argentina’s current hyperinflation) is tantamount to suggesting that opportunity cost, one of the most fundamental concepts in all of economics, is useless in explaining a choice among alternatives.

 

 

Mike Sproul
Nov 20 2023 at 7:31pm

To help appreciate the tautological nature of MV=Py, try applying it to stock valuation. Let M=# shares of GM held by the public, V=times per year that a share is spent (buying goods), P=#shares needed to buy a unit of goods (y). You would end up with a theory that says “GM shares spent”=”GM shares received”. Then ask yourself if any stock analyst has ever tried to use MV=Py to value shares of stock.

The main point of Sargent’s “Four Big Inflations” paper is that inflation stopped BEFORE money growth stopped. This contradicts the QT, but supports the BT view. People have argued about it, but it came nowhere near being roundly rejected.

 

vince
Nov 20 2023 at 7:37pm

 

No more a tautology than rt=d, the most used formula in physics and engineering.

 

Isn’t the difference that rt can be specified in advance, while velocity is an after-the-fact plug?

Monte
Nov 20 2023 at 9:24pm

I suppose, although V is typically estimated in advance based on historical evidence.  But that doesn’t make MV=Py a tautology.  Rather, it’s an accounting identity that remains a useful tool for understanding the factors that influence inflation.  And I suspect you’re more aware than me that d=rt is an equation, not an identity, where r is (usually) a constant.

In either case, neither is a tautology.

 

Comments are closed.

RECENT POST

The ideas that government must fund most basic research, that such research is crucial for advanced technology, and that advanced technology is a strong contributor to economic growth have all become cliches. Not only President Clinton, but also many others, assume that these ideas are true without bothering to examine...

Read More

How would you feel if you saw the following headline: "Gas stations to be saddled with major new tax on gasoline" Perhaps you might suspect that motorists will ultimately pay the higher gas tax. OK, so tell me how you feel reading this Bloomberg headline: Big Banks to Be Saddled With Tab for SVB, Signature De...

Read More

In my two previous posts (here and here) I described how hyperinflation hit the Weimar Republic after the end of World War 1. On November 15, 1923, the German Papiermark hit an exchange rate of 2.5 trillion to $1. Two weeks earlier, $1 had bought 133 billion marks; at the start of the year 17,972 marks; on the currency...

Read More