The Purchasing Power of Money
By Irving Fisher
THE purpose of this book is to set forth the principles determining the purchasing power of money and to apply those principles to the study of historical changes in that purchasing power, including in particular the recent change in “the cost of living,” which has aroused world-wide discussion.If the principles here advocated are correct, the purchasing power of money–or its reciprocal, the level of prices–depends exclusively on five definite factors: (1) the volume of money in circulation; (2) its velocity of circulation; (3) the volume of bank deposits subject to check; (4) its velocity; and (5) the volume of trade. Each of these five magnitudes is extremely definite, and their relation to the purchasing power of money is definitely expressed by an “equation of exchange.” In my opinion, the branch of economics which treats of these five regulators of purchasing power ought to be recognized and ultimately will be recognized as an exact science, capable of precise formulation, demonstration, and statistical verification…. [From the Preface to the First Edition]
First Pub. Date
1911
Publisher
New York: The Macmillan Co.
Pub. Date
1922
Comments
Assisted by Harry G. Brown (Instructor in Political Economy in Yale U.) 2nd edition. Harry G. Brown, assistant.
Copyright
The text of this edition is in the public domain.
- Preface to the First Edition
- Preface to the Second Edition
- Suggestions to Readers
- Addendum
- Chapter 1
- Chapter 2
- Chapter 3
- Chapter 4
- Chapter 5
- Chapter 6
- Chapter 7
- Chapter 8
- Chapter 9
- Chapter 10
- Chapter 11
- Chapter 12
- Chapter 13
- Appendix to Chapter II
- Appendix to Chapter III
- Appendix to Chapter V
- Appendix to Chapter VI
- Appendix to Chapter VII
- Appendix to Chapter VIII
- Appendix to Chapter X
- Appendix to Chapter XII
§ I (TO CHAPTER II, § 3)
The Concept of an Average
APPENDIX TO CHAPTER II
The subject of averages or means is so important—both theoretically and practically—and so little upon it is readily available for economic readers that a short statement of its fundamental principles may be fitly inserted here.
*1
There are numerous kinds of averages or means. Among them are the arithmetical, geometrical, and harmonical; and of each of these there are many different varieties. The
simple arithmetical mean of a specific series of terms is found by adding the terms together and dividing by their number. Thus, suppose it is desired to find a mean of 2 and 8. It is evidently
The
simple geometrical mean is obtained by multiplying all the terms together and extracting that root of the product which corresponds to the number of terms. Thus, the geometrical mean of 2 and 8 is
or 4.
The
simple harmonical mean of any number of terms is the reciprocal of the arithmetical average of their reciprocals. For 2 and 8 it is
The
weighted arithmetical mean is a modification of the simple arithmetical mean. Suppose it is desired to find the mean height of two groups of trees, one tall, the other short.
The tall group is 8 yards high, the short, 2. The
simple arithmetical mean as we have seen is 5. But this mean treats both groups as of equal importance. Let us suppose that there are twenty of the two-yard trees and ten of the eight-yard trees, and let us seek a mean of the two heights, such as will give equal importance to each
tree. This will give the short group of twenty trees twice the importance of the tall group of ten trees. We shall be giving equal importance to each tree if we take the simple arithmetical mean of the thirty trees. But this
simple mean of
thirty trees will be a
weighted mean of the
two groups of trees. It is to be found by adding their heights together (twenty heights of two yards plus ten of eight) and dividing by the number of trees (20 + 10). That is, the mean height is
two groups instead of that of the thirty trees) is said to be the weighted arithmetical mean of 2 and 8, the 2 being weighted twenty times, and the 8, ten times. The weighted mean of the two groups means the simple mean of the thirty trees. In other words when we “weight” the various terms averaged, we no longer count these terms once each, but we count one term as though it were (say) twenty, and another as though it were (say) ten and the number of times we count a term is its “weight.” In the same way we may define the weighted geometrical and weighted harmonical means. Taking the same example of the trees, we find the results to be respectively
or 3.175 and
The same results would have been obtained in each case if, instead of the weights 20 and 10, we had taken, as weights, 2 and 1.
Since there are so many different kinds of means, the question arises, What is the meaning of an average or mean in general? We answer: Any mean of a series of terms must be obtainable from them by a mathematical rule such that,
when applied to a series of
identical terms, it will make their mean identical with each of them. Any rule of averaging is admissible which is consistent with this condition (that the average of identical terms must be identical with each). We know that the simple arithmetical mean
A, of
a,b, and
c is
a,b, and
c in (
a +
b +
c)/3, we obtain
A; thus the test is satisfied.
Again, let
G be the geometrical mean of
a,b, and
c; so that
G =
This formula also conforms to the definition of a mean because
G =
.
Similarly, the harmonical average (which we may call
H) of
a,b, and
c is
For a weighted arithmetical average
A
w of
a,b,c, the weights being
a,
b,
g, we have the formula
By applying this general rule, we can make at will innumerable kinds of averages. It is only necessary to write any formula twice, once using the terms to be averaged and once using, instead, the required average, and then equate the two. Thus, let us take the complicated formula
new species of average (
x) of
a,b, and
c, simply by equating it with the similar form
x as determined by this equation will conform to our definition of an average is evident, since substituting
x for
a,b, and
c, the equation becomes a truism, showing that the proposed new average of the identical terms
x is
x.
A special case of the definition, requiring particular mention, is that in which two or more means (not necessarily of the same kind) are related to one another. In order that
A should be a mean of
a1,
a2,
a3,…when we know that
B is a mean of
b1,
b2,
b3,…it is only necessary to have a determining formula such that if
a1 =
a2 =
a3…and at the same time
b1 =
b2 =
b3…(each of which by hypothesis must be equal to
B), then
A shall also be equal to each of the magnitudes
a1,
a2,
a3, etc. Many examples of pairs of means like
A and
B will be given in Chapter X (on the construction of index numbers). The following is a simple example:—
Let
nAB =
a1b1 +
a2b2 +
a3b3 +…and let
B be the arithmetical mean =
n being the number of terms). Then
A is a (new) sort of mean of
a1,
a2,
a3; for, substituting
A for
a1,
a2,
a3,… and
B for
b1,
b2,
b3, in the equation
nAB =
a1b1 +…, the equation is satisfied.
§ 2 (TO CHAPTER II, § 5)
The Concept of Velocity of Circulation
The velocity of circulation of money has been defined as a ratio of the money expended to the average money on hand, that is, as a rate of turnover. A rate of turnover differs from the popular concept of velocity. The latter regards velocity as the average number of times money changes hands from one person to another; whereas, the concept we have employed treats velocity as the average number of coins which
pass through
one man’s hands, divided by the average amount held by him. The difference between the two concepts is very similar to that between two methods of obtaining the velocity of a railway train. One method is to follow the train for a certain number of miles, and note how long a time it takes to travel those miles. The other is to stand on a certain spot beside the track and note the time consumed by a given length of train in passing that spot. Following the train from place to place is like following a coin from person to person, while watching the train pass one point is like observing the rate of turnover of one person’s purse. We may distinguish the two methods as the “coin-transfer” method and the “person-turnover” method. Both methods, if correctly employed, yield the same result. But in the coin-transfer method, an important distinction is usually overlooked, the distinction between the gross and net circulation of money. What is desired is the rate at which money is used for
purchasing goods, not for “making change.” The result is the difference between the number of times each piece changes hands
against goods, and the number of times it changes hands
with goods. If a $10 bill is transferred in purchase of goods and $2 is given back “in change,” the actual money expended for goods is measured, not by $12, the gross transfer of money, nor yet by $10, the gross amount transferred against goods, but by $8, the net amount paid for goods.
If it is desired, in the coin-transfer method, to learn the average velocity of circulation of two pieces of money, such as a dollar and a ten-cent piece, we must not only find the
net rate of turnover of each coin, but also take account of the discrepancy between the buying efficiencies of the two coins. Let it be assumed that during the year the dollar is passed 115 times against goods and 15 times with goods, so that its net velocity of circulation is 115 – 15 or 100. If we suppose the velocity of the ten-cent piece to be 290 – 90 or 200, the average velocity of the two must somehow take account of the different values of different denominations. A dollar is the equivalent of ten dimes. Its rapidity of circulation
should therefore be “weighted” tenfold in order to get the real average, that is, the average of the
service performed by the two. The net rate of circulation of 100 for the dollar is equivalent to a net velocity of circulation of 100 for each and every one of
ten dimes. It follows that the average velocity of the two coins is
*2
There is yet another magnitude which should be considered in connection with the velocity of monetary circulation. This may be called the
average time of turnover, i.e. the average amount of time consumed by all the given money, in being turned over once. This is the “reciprocal” of velocity. If money changes hands twenty times in a year, it turns over, on the average, once in 1/20 of a year, or once in somewhat over 18 days. This is its
average time of turnover. If the average velocity of circulation or rate of turnover is forty times a year, then the average time of turnover is 1/40 of a year or about 9 days. Or, instead of considering all the given money directly, let us come at it through a component part of it. If a man having, on the average, $10 in his pocket every day, expends on the average $1 a day, he evidently turns over 1/10 of his money each day. Since to turn over 1/10 of his average stock each day is to turn over the whole of it 36½ times a year or once in 10 days, the time of turnover will be 10 days. If the man under consideration had a pocketbook arranged with a series of ten one dollar bills, and every day, as one was taken from the top to be expended, another were added at the bottom, evidently any and every bill would remain in his hands just ten days traveling from the bottom to the top of the pile.
§ 3 (TO CHAPTER II, § 5)
“Arrays” of p’s, Q’s, and pQ’s
Let us assume that the year is divided into an indefinite number of periods, or moments, and distinguish the prices and quantities relating to those successive periods by the subscripts 1, 2, 3, etc., at the left; and that we are dealing with a community of an indefinite number of persons, distinguished likewise by subscripts at the right. Thus the quantity of a particular kind of goods purchased by individual No. 1 in moment No. 3 is represented by
3q1 and the price of the sale by
3p1. The entire system of quantities and prices is represented by the two following “arrays.”
PERSONS | PERIODS
|
TOTAL | PERSONS | PERIODS
|
AVERAGE | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 2 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 3 | ||||
1 | 1q1 | 2q1 | 3q1 | Q1 | 1 | 1p1 | 2p1 | 3p1 | p1 |
2 | 1q2 | 2q2 | 3q2 | Q2 | 2 | 1p2 | 2p2 | 3p2 | p2 |
3 | 1q3 | 2q3 | 3q3 | Q3 | 3 | 1p3 | 2p3 | 3p3 | p3 |
— | — | — | — | — | — | — | — | — | — |
— | — | — | — | — | — | — | — | — | — |
Total | 1Q | 2Q | 3Q | Q | Average | 1p | 2p | 3p | p |
We have just stated the meaning of the letters
inside these arrays. Those outside are as follows:
Q1 is the total quantity bought by person 1 and is the sum (
1q1 +
2q1 +
3q1 +…) of all quantities purchased by him in all the different periods of time. Like definitions apply to
Q2,
Q3, etc.
1Q is the total quantity purchased in moment 1 and is the sum (
1q1 +
1q2 +
1q3 +…) of all quantities purchased in that moment by all the different persons. Like definitions apply to
2Q,3Q,…. Finally
Q is (as already employed in the text) the grand total of quantities bought by all persons in all periods of time. Evidently,
p array, but the relations to the letters inside are here averages instead of sums. We may best derive the form of these averages from a third or intermediate array for
pQ indicating the money values of the purchases.
This last named array is
PERSONS | PERIODS
|
TOTAL | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 2 | 3 | ||
1 | 1p11q1 | 2p12q1 | 3p13q1 | p1Q1 |
2 | 1p21q2 | 2p22q2 | 3p23q2 | p2Q2 |
3 | 1p31q3 | 2p32q3 | 3p33q3 | p3Q3 |
Total | 1p1Q | 2p2Q | 3p3Q | pQ |
In this array the same relations must evidently hold as in the
Q array. That is,
pQ, the entire sum spent on the given commodity by all persons in the community during all periods of the year, must be equal to (1) the sum of the column above it, (2) the sum of the row at its left, and (3) the sum of the interior terms of the array. In other words, it must be equal to (1) the sum of the total yearly amounts spent by the many different persons, (2) the sum of the total amounts spent in the community at the many different periods of the year, and (3) the sum of the purchases of all the individuals in all the periods.
The nature of the
p array is now determined by the
Q and the
pQ arrays. It must namely be such as to permit the summation just described for the
pQ array. That is, each of the average prices (such as
p1) must conform to the type of formula:—
Hence,
p is a weighted average of
1p1,
2p1, etc., the weights being
1q1,
2q1, etc. That is, the average price paid by person No. 1 is the weighted arithmetical average of the prices paid by him at different moments through the year, the weights being the quantities bought. The same principle obtains for all other persons.
Similarly, the average price,
1p, may be shown to be
Finally, the average price,
p, in the lower right corner of the
p array, is either
p is a weighted arithmetical average of
p1,
p2, etc., the weights being
Q1,
Q2, etc.; or (using the row instead of column),
p is the like weighted arithmetical average of
1p,2p, etc., the weights being
1Q,2Q, etc.; or lastly, either of these two expressions for
p, combined with the preceding expression for
p1,
p2, etc., or with that for
1p,2p, etc., may be used to show that
p is a weighted arithmetical average of all the
p‘s within the array, the weights being the corresponding
q‘s. In short, the price of each commodity for the year is its average at all times and for all purchases in the year weighted according to the quantities bought.
This principle covers the method of averaging prices in different localities. Thus the average price of sugar in 1909 in the United States is the weighted arithmetical average of all prices of sales by all individuals throughout the United States, and at all moments throughout the year, the weights being the quantities bought. Thus, if there are large local or temporal variations in price, it is important to give chief weight to the largest purchases.
What has been said as to
Q and
p arrays relates only to one commodity. But the same principles apply to each commodity yielding separate arrays corresponding to each of the total quantities,
Q,Q‘,
Q”, etc., as well as corresponding to each of the average prices,
p,p‘,
p”, etc.
§ 4 (TO CHAPTER II, § 5)
“Arrays” of e’s, m’s, and V’s
In the preceding section we have seen that there exists an “array” of
p‘s,
pQ‘s and
Q‘s for each commodity. These relate to the right side of the equation of exchange. Similar arrays relate to the left side.
If, as before, we assume a community of any number of persons, distinguished respectively by subscripts at the right, and if we divide the year into moments, distinguished by subscripts at the left, we may designate the amount of money expended in the first moment by the first person as
1e1, the average amount of money he has on hand at that moment as
1m1 and his velocity of circulation at that moment (reckoned at its rate per year) as
1V1. The expenditure in the moment being
1e1, that moment’s rate per annum is
1n11e1, there being
n moments in the year, so that the velocity of circulation or rate of turnover per annum,
1V1, is
In the first table,
E1 at the right of the first line is the sum expended by the first person, being the sum of
1e1,
2e1,
3e1,…in the first line representing the amounts expended by him at successive moments during the year. Likewise,
E2 is the sum expended by the second person during the year, and
E3 is the sum expended by the third.
1E at the foot of the first column is the amount expended by all persons in
the first moment; that is, it is the sum of all the amounts in the column above it;
2E is likewise the amount expended by all persons in the second moment;
3E, the amount expended in the third, etc. Finally,
E, in the lower right-hand corner, is, as employed in the text, the grand total expended by
all persons in
all moments of the year. Evidently
E can be obtained by adding the row to the left of it, or by adding the column above it. It is also the sum of all the elements inside the lines,
i.e.E =
S1E =
SE1 =
S1e1.
In the second table,
M in the lower right corner is a sum of the average amounts held by the different members of
the community during the year,
i.e. it is the sum of the elements in the column above it,
m1,
m2,
m3, etc., each of which is by hypothesis a simple average of the row to its left.
Or, again,
M is a simple average of the row to its left,
1M,2M,3M, etc., the average amounts of money in the community, in the successive moments of the year, each of which averages is in turn the sum of the column above it,
i.e.
M is both the sum of averages and the average of sums. That the two are equal follows by expressing both in terms of the elementary quantities
1m1 by means of the equations
1M =
1m1 +
1m2 +
1m3 +….It is, of course, easy also to express
M directly in terms of
1m1, etc., within the table. Thus expressed, it is
The third table (that for velocities) is derived from the other two. As just explained,
1V1 is the velocity of circulation (considered as a
per annum rate) for the first person in the community in the first moment.
There remain to be shown the relations of the elements in the
V table.
Form (1) shows that
V is a weighted average of the yearly velocities of the different persons, the velocity of each person being for the entire year and weighted according to his average amount of money on hand.
Following an analogous but slightly different sequence, we have
Form (2) shows that
V is also the weighted average of the yearly velocities of the successive moments into which the year is divided, the velocity of each moment being for the entire community and weighted according to its average amount of money then in circulation.
Thus form (1) gives
V in terms of the column above it, while form (2) gives
V in terms of the row at its left. A formula similar to (1) may be constructed to express each of the magnitudes
1V,2V,3V, etc., in terms of the column above it, while a formula similar to (2) may be constructed to express each of the magnitudes
V1,
V2,
V3, etc., in terms of the row at its left. That is, the velocity in the entire community at any particular moment is a specific form of average of the velocities of different persons at that moment; and the velocity for the entire year of any particular person is a specific form of average of the velocities at different moments for that person.
Finally,
V may be expressed, not only as an average of its
column and row as in formula (1) and (2), but also as an average of the magnitudes in the interior of the table. This last result may be obtained in several ways, of which the most direct may briefly be expressed as follows: We know that
E is the sum of the interior of the first or
E table, that is,
E =
S1e1; and that
M is equal to
V is the weighted arithmetical average of the yearly velocities pertaining to different persons in different moments, each velocity being weighted by the amount of money on hand in that instance. The mathematical reader will perceive that an alternative treatment would derive the result in terms of an
harmonic average.
§ 5 (TO CHAPTER II, § 5)
The Coin-transfer Concept of Velocity and the Concept of Time of Turnover
We now turn to the coin-transfer concept of velocity of circulation. To show what kind of an average
V is of the velocity of circulation of individual coins, or rather of individual pieces of money in general, let us denote the values of the individual pieces of money circulating in the community by the letters
a,b,c,d, etc., and let us denote the
net velocity of circulation of these (the number of times exchanged
against goods
minus the number of times exchanged
with goods or “in change”) by
h,i,j,k, respectively, etc. Then
E, the total amount expended, is denoted by
ha +
ib +
jc +
kd +…; and the amount of money,
M, in the community is
a +
b +
c +
d.
E/M is a weighted average of the net velocities of circulation of the different pieces of money, the velocity of each piece being weighted according to its denomination. But
E/M is also
V, which we have already seen is the velocity of circulation in the person-turnover sense.
It is clear, therefore, that the coin-transfer method of averaging is the same in results as the person-turnover method, if all the pieces of money in the community are included.
Finally, we come to the concept of “time of turnover.”
If velocity of circulation is represented as
V, then 1/
V represents the time of turnover. Similarly, the reciprocals of
1V,2V,…,
V1,
V2,…,
1V1,
1V2,…,
2V1,…, are corresponding times of turnover. Using
W for the reciprocal of
V and applying the appropriate subscripts, we may write an array of
W‘s analogous to the previous array of
V‘s, and we may show that
W is an average of
W1,
W2, or of
1W,2W,… or of
1W1,
1W2,…,
2W1,…
But these averages are all
harmonic averages. To see this, we need only remember that
V has already been analyzed
*3 as a weighted average of the elementary
V‘s, and that
W has been defined as the reciprocal of
V. That is,
W is the reciprocal of this weighted average of elementary
V‘s. But the elementary
W‘s are reciprocals of the elementary
V‘s. In other words,
W is the reciprocal of the weighted arithmetical average of the reciprocals of elementary
W‘s. This
makes
W, by definition, a weighted
harmonic average of these elementary magnitudes.
§ 6 (TO CHAPTER II, § 5)
Algebraic Demonstration of Equation of Exchange
It is clear that the equation of exchange,
MV =
SpQ, is derived from elementary equations expressing the equivalence of purchase money and goods bought. The money expended by any particular person at any particular moment is, by the very concept of price, equal to the quantities of all commodities bought in that moment by that person multiplied by the prices,
i.e.
1p11q1 +
1p‘
11q‘
1 +
1p‘
11q‘
1 +…
e‘s which we call
E; and for the right side the sum of all the
pq‘s. We have already seen in the text how the left side,
E, may be converted (by multiplying and dividing by
M) into
MV, and we have also just seen (§ 3 of this Appendix) how the sum of all the terms relating to each particular commodity represented on the right side may be converted (by similar simple algebraic operations) into one term of the form
pQ so that the whole sum becomes
SpQ. The final result is, therefore,
MV =
SpQ. This reasoning constitutes, therefore, a demonstration of the truth of this formula, based on the simple elementary truth that in every exchange the money expended equals the quantity bought multiplied by the price of sale.
§ 7 (TO CHAPTER II, § 5)
P must be a Specific Form of Average in order to vary directly as M and V and inversely as the Q’s
Let us assume that
V and the
Q‘s remain invariable while
M changes to
Mo and
p,p‘,
p‘, etc. to
po,
p‘
o,
p‘
o, etc.
(The subscripts “0” refer to a year called the base year other than the original year.) We have for the two years respectively the two equations:—
poQ,p‘
oQ‘, etc. We conclude that, if the velocity of circulation and the quantities of goods exchanged remain unaltered, while the quantity of money is altered in a given ratio, then prices will change in this same ratio “on the average,” the average being exactly defined as a
weighted arithmetical average, in which the weights are the
values of goods sold, reckoned at the prices of the
base year. The ratio may evidently also be written:—
weighted harmonic average of
pQ,p‘
Q‘, etc., that is, the values, not in the base year, but the other year.
If
M and the
Q‘s remain invariable, while
V changes from
V to
V1, evidently the ratio
V/
V1 will be expressed by precisely the same formulæ as above.
If the
Q‘s remain invariable, while
M and
V both change, evidently the ratio
Again the same formulæ apply if
M and
V remain invariable while the
Q‘s all vary
in a given ratio, or if the
Q‘s all vary
in a given ratio in combination with any variation in
M or
V or both. In short, the formulae apply perfectly in all cases of variation, except when the
Q‘s vary
relatively to each other.
These formulæ, it should be noted, are those later discussed as the formulae numbered (11) in the large table of formulæ in the Appendix to Chapter X.